ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT IN THE DEVELOPING
E-BOOK MARKET: APPLE, AMAZON, AND THE
FUTURE OF THE PUBLISHING INDUSTRY
Zachary C. Flood
In United States v. Apple, Inc., a panel of the United States Court of
Appeals for the Second Circuit considered whether Apple orchestrated a
conspiracy with major book publishing firms to raise the price of e-books in
violation of Section One of the Sherman Act.
1
Apple negotiated with book
publishers to secure content deals for its planned e-book application and
platform in the lead up to its introduction of the iPad in 2010. The
publishers, eager to break up Amazon’s dominance over the e-book market
and to raise retail e-book prices, welcomed the negotiations with Apple as
a means to achieve both. Reviewing the collusive nature of the negotiations,
the Second Circuit held that Apple violated the Sherman Act by using its
talks and resulting contracts with each of the publishing firms to effectuate
a horizontal price-fixing agreement.
2
Critically, the court also found that
Apple’s conduct was per se illegal under the Sherman Act, and thus did not
require proof that the agreement actually harmed competition.
3
The Apple decision is the latest chapter in an ongoing saga over the
proper application of the per se rule in antitrust law. Over the past half-
century—inspired by influential shifts in economic thinking—courts have
reigned in their application of the per se rule to vertical restraints.
4
Courts
increasingly review these restraints under what is known as the rule of
reason, a probing analysis of a given agreement’s procompetitive and
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.15779/Z38V865
© 2016 Zachary C. Flood.
J.D. Candidate, 2016, University of California, Berkeley, School of Law.
1. United States v. Apple, Inc. (Apple II), 791 F.3d 290, 340 (2d Cir. 2015). Section
One of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, serves as one of the primary antitrust enforcement
statutes.
2. Id. at 339.
3. Id. at 321.
4. See P
HILLIP AREEDA, LOUIS KAPLOW & AARON S. EDLIN, ANTITRUST
ANALYSIS407 (7th ed. 2013). A vertical restraint is a limitation on competition between
firms at different levels within a given market, such as a limit on maximum retail price
imposed by a manufacturer on a local seller. By contrast, a horizontal restraint is a
limitation on competition between firms at the same level within a given market—
horizontal competitors—such as an agreement establishing a maximum retail price
between two local sellers.
880 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
anticompetitive potential. At the heart of this shift in approach is the
increasingly popular view that certain vertical agreements may lead to
procompetitive effects, and thus should not be condemned without a more
nuanced exploration of their effects on consumer welfare. The Apple court
considered whether Apple’s conduct qualified for this more lenient form of
analysis, ultimately concluding that it did not.
The conduct at issue in Apple also represents a fascinating opportunity
to explore the use of the per se rule in the context of a rapidly changing and
ever-more important digital content market. The facts of this case illustrate
the challenges that established firms—like the publishers here—can face
during times of disruptive change. The court’s decision makes clear that
conduct in these changing markets is not exempt from the normal
application of the antitrust laws.
This Note considers the Second Circuit’s decision to apply the per se
rule to Apple’s conduct and explores how antitrust law has impacted the
publishing industry. Part I explains the history of the per se rule and the
reasons why courts have abandoned it for certain types of restraints. Part II
provides background to the case, detailing the agreements between Apple
and the publishers. Part III summarizes the Second Circuit’s decision. In
Part IV, the Note discusses three discrete ideas in separate Sections. The
first Section discusses the Second Circuit’s decision to apply the per se rule
despite the presence of vertical restraints. This Section concludes that this
was the proper decision given the nature of the agreement between Apple
and the publishers, and the economic and administrative rationales
associated with the per se rule. The next Section discusses—and rejects—
Apple’s proposed “Facilitating Market Entry” Exception to the per se rule.
Finally, the last Section considers how antitrust law and the Apple decision
could affect the future of the rapidly changing publishing industry.
I. THE HISTORY OF THE PER SE RULE AND THE RULE
OF REASON
Section One of the Sherman Act (“the Act”) bans every “contract,
combination . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce.”
5
Early
on, the Supreme Court struggled with Section One’s expansive language.
The Court initially held that the Act banned literally all restraints on trade,
rejecting a more limited reading that would condemn only unreasonable
restraints because it believed that judges lacked the expertise and reliable
5. Sherman Act § 1, 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2004).
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 881
standards necessary for evaluating reasonableness.
6
Eventually, however, the
Court adopted the view that the Act banned only unreasonable restraints,
as measured under a rule of reason.
7
The Court later elaborated that the
application of the rule of reason required a searching analysis of the given
restraint and its context to determine whether, on balance, it “merely
regulates and perhaps thereby promotes competition or whether it is such
as may suppress or even destroy competition.”
8
Despite the adoption of the rule of reason as the baseline mode of
Section One analysis, courts began applying a rule of per se illegality to
certain types of restraints with clear anticompetitive potential throughout
the early part of the twentieth century.
9
Among the categories of restraints
held to be illegal per se during this period were horizontal price-fixing;
10
vertical agreements to set minimum prices,
11
maximum prices,
12
and non-
price restraints;
13
division of markets;
14
group boycotts;
15
and tying
arrangements.
16
The underlying judicial perception was that, on balance,
these types of restraints were so overwhelmingly likely to yield
anticompetitive versus procompetitive results that individual cases did not
merit an in-depth rule of reason analysis. Instead, courts deemed these
restraints to be per se anticompetitive.
Beginning in the 1970s, however, the immensely influential brand of
conservative economic theory known as the Chicago School called into
question the widespread use of the per se rule.
17
This new economic
6. See United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Ass’n, 166 U.S. 290, 331–32 (1897)
(“[I]t is exceedingly difficult to formulate even the terms of the rule itself which should
govern in the matter . . . .”).
7. Standard Oil Co. of N.J. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 60 (1911).
8. Bd. of Trade of City of Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918) (“To
determine that question the court must ordinarily consider the facts peculiar to the business
to which the restraint is applied; its condition before and after the restraint was imposed;
the nature of the restraint and its effect, actual or probable.”)
9. See, e.g., United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 223–24 (1940)
(establishing the per se illegality of price-fixing).
10. Id. at 210.
11. See generally Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373
(1911), overruled by Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007).
12. Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968), overruled by State Oil Co. v. Khan,
522 U.S. 3 (1997).
13. United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967), overruled by Cont’l
T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
14. United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271 (6th Cir. 1898), aff'd as
modified, 175 U.S. 211 (1899).
15. Fashion Originators’ Guild of Am. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 312 U.S. 457, 688 (1941).
16. Int’l Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392, 395 (1947).
17. See A
REEDA & KAPLOW, supra note 4, at ¶ 400.
882 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
thinking challenged the assumptions about the economic effects of certain
types of arrangements that courts had previously deemed per se illegal.
These new economic perspectives had a profound impact on the way many
courts and commentators viewed vertical restraints.
18
During this period, Chicago School antitrust scholars began identifying
a variety of situations in which they believed vertical restraints had the
potential to benefit consumer welfare. Two observations in particular led to
significant changes in the way courts approach vertical agreements. First,
agreements between manufacturers and retailers that reduce price,
territorial, or other forms of competition between retailers could increase
overall output by allowing retailers to invest in promoting the
manufacturer’s product.
19
For example, a reduction in price competition
between two local retailers as regards a given product might increase both
of their overall sales by allowing each of them to focus on their marketing
and salesmanship of that product, without fear that their competitor would
charge lower prices and free-ride off their promotional investment. Second,
a manufacturer’s efforts to set maximum retail prices may increase sales and
output by limiting dealer markups, constraining the dealer’s ability to
leverage its market power.
20
The first insight eventually led the Supreme Court to its initial decision
to backpedal on the application of the per se rule. In Continental T.V., Inc.
v. GTE Sylvania Inc., the Court held that the effects of vertical non-price
restraints imposed by a manufacturer on a retail distributor were sufficiently
ambiguous to warrant analysis under the rule of reason, overruling its prior
decision in United States v. Arnold Schwinn & Co.
21
In an effort to revive its
struggling television sales, Sylvania abandoned its wholesale distribution
model and began selling directly to local retailers on a franchise model.
22
As
part of the arrangement, Sylvania imposed geographic restraints on retailers,
limiting where they could sell their products.
23
In holding that these
restraints should be analyzed under the rule of reason, the Court focused on
the complex potential for vertical restraints to boost interbrand competition
(competition between manufacturers) at the relative expense of intrabrand
18. Id.
19. Id. at ¶ 409.
20. Id. at ¶ 408. Though this second insight is not discussed here, it eventually led
the Supreme Court to reverse course on the application of the per se rule in cases of
vertically imposed restrictions on maximum retail price. See State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522
U.S. 3 (1997).
21. Cont’l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 59 (1977).
22. Id. at 38.
23. Id.
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 883
competition (competition between retailers in the sale of a given product).
24
The Court determined the “redeeming virtues” of increased interbrand
competition were enough to dispel the notion that such restraints lacked
any redeeming value such that they should be proscribed per se.
25
Twenty years later, the Supreme Court invoked similar reasoning to
reverse course on the use of the per se rule in the context of vertical restraints
on minimum retail price, or price floors. In Leegin v. PSKS, the Court held
in a 5-4 decision that a manufacturer’s use of retail price maintenance
(RPM) to set minimum prices for its services held enough procompetitive
potential to justify rule of reason, rather than per se, scrutiny.
26
Once again,
the Court highlighted economic literature suggesting that, absent such price
floors, “the retail services that enhance interbrand competition might be
underprovided.”
27
Justice Breyer dissented. Enumerating the arguments for
and against the competitive impact of minimum RPM, Breyer sharpened
his inquiry on the per se rule’s costs and benefits—the tradeoff between
foreclosing some potentially beneficial conduct on the one hand, and
promoting efficient enforcement activity and smooth judicial
administration on the other.
28
Breyer conceded that it was a difficult
decision, but ultimately fell back on stare decisis and Congress’s lack of
intervention in the longstanding application of the per se rule, breaking
from the majority’s decision to apply the rule of reason to vertical
restraints.
29
While the Supreme Court has marched back the application of the per
se rule in the context of vertical restraints, the rule continues to play an
important role in other areas of antitrust law. Most prominently, the per se
rule is thoroughly entrenched in the realm of horizontal agreements
between competitors to fix prices or to divide markets.
30
Still, even among
24. Id. at 51–56.
25. Id. at 51–59. The Court further noted the view of some economic theorists,
particularly Robert Bork, that manufacturers have a natural incentive to maintain as much
intrabrand competition as is consistent with the efficient distribution of their product.
However, the Court also highlighted the lack of consensus on this point. Id. at 56.
26. Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, 551 U.S. 877, 904 (2007).
27. Id. at 890.
28. Id. at 914–17 (Breyer, J., dissenting).
29. Id. at 919–20.
30. See Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643, 647 (1980) (describing a
horizontal agreement to fix prices as the “archetypal” per se violation); Verizon Commc’ns
Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 408 (2004) (referring to
horizontal price-fixing as thesupreme evil” of antitrust law); Palmer v. BRG of Ga., Inc.,
498 U.S. 46, 49–50 (1990) (per curium) (finding scheme to divide national market for bar
review materials per se illegal).
884 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
this category of restraints, the Court has made exceptions where it has found
compelling reasons to presume a given horizontal restraint might yield
procompetitive benefits.
For example, in the definitive case of Broadcast Music Inc. v. Columbia
Broadcast System, Inc. (“BMI”), the Court held that BMI—one of the two
main performing rights organizations in charge of licensing musical
performance rights and collecting royalties under a blanket license fee—
though a literal horizontal combination engaging in price-fixing, was
entitled to escape per se condemnation under Section One.
31
The Court
concluded that certain market failures within the music licensing market
made BMI’s creation of a blanket license with a set price an innovative and
potentially efficient development.
32
The Court has characterized this and
other analogous decisions as situations in which “restraints on competition
are essential if the product is to be available at all.”
33
Notwithstanding these exceptions, the Court has generally drawn a
dividing line between horizontal and vertical restraints, applying per se
treatment to the former, and rule of reason treatment to the latter. But what
if the conspiracy at issue involves agreements between both horizontally and
vertically situated actors? This situation arises in so-called “hub-and-spoke”
conspiracies in which many horizontal actors coordinate their activity
through their interactions with a vertically situated actor.
34
For example,
where a number of manufacturers decide to fix prices, they can then insist
that a vertically situated retailer adopt a vertical restraint imposing a high
price floor on each of them, thereby granting each manufacturer assurance
that the others will be bound to that price floor. The Apple case grapples
with what standard to apply where vertical restraints are used as part of
horizontal conspiracies.
31. BMI, 441 U.S. 1, 21–24 (1979). For another landmark case in which the Court
rejected application of the per se rule to horizontal price-fixing, see National Collegiate
Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85 (1984).
32. Specifically, the Court focused on the transaction costs inherent in requiring
consumers to negotiate individual licenses with each artist, and the difficulties artists in
turn faced in policing unlicensed use of their works. BMI, 441 U.S. at 35 n.30.
33. Am. Needle, Inc. v. Nat’l Football League, 560 U.S. 183, 203 (2010).
34. See, e.g., In re Musical Instruments & Equip. Antitrust Litig., 798 F.3d 1186,
1192 (9th Cir. 2015) (“[T]he line between horizontal and vertical restraints can blur. One
conspiracy can involve both direct competitors and actors up and down the supply chain,
and hence consist of both horizontal and vertical agreements.”).
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 885
II. U.S. V. APPLE: FACTS AND PROCEDURAL HISTORY
On January 27, 2010, Apple, Inc. (“Apple”) unveiled the iPad, a tablet
device that marked a significant advance in consumer electronics. As part of
the iPad’s elaborate launch presentation, Apple showed off the iBookstore,
its new online marketplace for e-books. During his presentation, Apple’s
CEO Steve Jobs used the iBookstore app to make a live purchase of the
New York Times bestselling book True Compass. The list price for Jobs’s
purchase was $14.99, a price 50% greater than that charged by e-book
pioneer and then-dominant retail player Amazon, Inc. Following the
presentation, when a reporter asked Jobs how Apple would be able to
compete with Amazon with prices 50 percent higher, Jobs confidently
responded that they would not have to; that book publishers would force
Amazon to raise its prices, and—infamously—that “the price will be the
same.”
35
A. APPLE SEES AN OPPORTUNITY WHEN AMAZON AND
PUBLISHERS FIGHT
Amazon, Inc. (“Amazon”) established itself as the dominant force in the
e-book market through the early introduction of its Kindle e-book reader
in November 2007, and its associated online e-book marketplace. Though
Amazon controlled an estimated ninety percent of the e-book market at the
beginning of 2010,
36
it found itself in a contentious relationship with the
book publishing industry; specifically, the “Big Six” publishing firms.
37
The
publishers were against Amazon’s practice of pricing its e-books—even new
releases and bestsellers—at what the publishers saw as an unreasonably low
$9.99. They feared that Amazon’s pricing practices were eroding
consumers’ value perception of their offerings and undercutting demand for
their more profitable new release, hardcover, print offerings.
38
The publishers pursued a variety of strategies to get Amazon to increase
its retail e-book prices. Prior to 2010, the publishers sold e-books to
Amazon wholesale, charging Amazon a fixed fee for every e-book it sold.
39
When publishers raised the wholesale price they charged Amazon above
$9.99, to nearly $13, Amazon reacted by maintaining its retail pricing and
pursing a loss-leader strategy, incurring a loss on each e-book it sold in order
35. Apple II, 791 F.3d 290, 308 (2015).
36. Id. at 299.
37. The “Big Six” firms at the time consisted of: Hachette, HarperCollins,
Macmillan, Penguin, Random House, and Simon & Schuster. Id. at 298.
38. Id. at 299.
39. Id.
886 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
to incentivize consumers to invest in the Kindle platform.
40
Various
publishers subsequently experimented with “windowing” their releases in
order to move Amazon on its pricing, refusing to sell e-book versions of
their new releases to Amazon for a set period following the release of initial
hardcover editions.
41
As the publishers realized, however, windowing was a
desperate and counter-productive strategy because it harmed customers,
promoted piracy, and hurt long-term sales.
42
Ultimately, while each of the Big Six hoped to move Amazon to increase
the price of its e-books, they suffered from a collective action problem. Each
of the Big Six was hesitant to challenge Amazon individually. As the
dominant retailer of both e-books and—more importantly—physical books,
Amazon possessed enormous power to retaliate against any individual
publisher that took a hard line over e-book pricing by disrupting that
publisher’s physical book sales.
43
In the lead up to the iPad’s launch, Eddy Cue, Apple’s Senior Vice
President of Internet Software and Services and the director of Apple’s
digital content stores, saw an opportunity to develop a proprietary e-book
marketplace for the iPad. He recognized the publishers’ disdain for
Amazon’s pricing model and their unsuccessful attempts to change it, and
anticipated that the Big Six would eagerly help facilitate Apple’s entry into
the e-book distribution market in order to gain negotiating leverage over
Amazon. In Cue’s own words to Jobs, “[t]he book publishers would do
almost anything for [Apple] to get into the ebook business.”
44
B. THE AGREEMENT BETWEEN APPLE AND THE PUBLISHERS
Two months before the iPad’s release, Apple reached out to the Big Six
about providing content for its proposed iBookstore. Cue and the publishers
negotiated at break-neck speed in order to come to an agreement in time to
announce the iBookstore at the iPad launch event.
45
Ultimately, Apple
agreed to a series of terms with five of the Big Six that all but guaranteed an
increase in e-book prices.
46
First, the parties agreed that Apple would distribute e-books under an
“agency”—as opposed to a wholesale—model.
47
Under this agreement,
40. Id.
41. Id. at 300–01.
42. Id. at 301.
43. Id. at 300.
44. Id. at 301.
45. Id. at 301–03.
46. Random House was the lone holdout. Id. at 308.
47. Id. at 302–04.
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 887
publishers would set retail prices themselves and Apple would collect thirty
percent of all e-book sales revenue. However, Apple feared that publishers
would set prices too high, infuriating customers and embarrassing the
iBookstore. Consequently, Apple included “price-ceilings” of $9.99,
$12.99, and $14.99 for certain types of releases.
48
Second, each of the five
publishers agreed to a Most Favored Nation (MFN) clause with Apple that
required publishers to set iBookstore retail prices no higher than those
charged by any other e-book retailer.
49
C. THE EFFECT OF THE AGREEMENT
Combined, the agency pricing and MFN terms meant that publishers
would be forced to sell e-books at $9.99 on the iBookstore in order to match
Amazon’s retail price, and would make less than $7 on each of those sales,
significantly less than the $13 they earned from each of their wholesale e-
book sales with Amazon. Thus, the only way the deal made economic sense
for each publisher was if they demanded a shift toward higher retail pricing
from Amazon, which they had previously been too afraid to do, for fear of
retribution.
Critically, throughout the negotiations, Apple and the publishers freely
shared information regarding their progress on these terms.
50
With each of
the five publishers aware that the others were similarly entering into deals
that would force them to confront Amazon, the final deal with Apple solved
the publishers’ collective action problem and forced them all to work
together toward moving Amazon toward an agency model and raising retail
prices for e-books.
In the months that followed, that is exactly what happened. The
publishers, led by Macmillan, each began negotiations with Amazon
designed to force it to switch to an agency model, sharing information with
each other as they did so.
51
Unable to stand up to five of the Big Six,
Amazon ultimately relented, switching to an agency model with all five by
June 2010. In short time, retail prices of e-books rose to the cap levels
provided for in each of the publishers’ deals with Apple.
52
Notably, during
the period following the price increase the five publishers saw an estimated
14.5% decline in their sales of e-books.
53
48. Id. at 304–05.
49. Id.
50. Id. at 305–08.
51. Id. 309–10.
52. Id. at 310.
53. Id.
888 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
D. PROCEDURAL HISTORY
On April 11, 2012, the Department of Justice and various State
Attorneys General filed two civil antitrust cases against Apple and the five
Publisher Defendants.
54
By August 12, 2013, all of the Publisher
Defendants had settled, entering into materially similar consent decrees
with the Department of Justice curtailing their ability to set, alter, or reduce
a retailer like Amazon’s ability to set or reduce the price of any e-book.
55
Refusing to settle, Apple instead opted for a bench trial on the issues of
liability and injunctive relief.
56
After a three week trial, on March 22, 2013
the District Court held that Apple had engaged in a per se violation of
Section One of the Sherman Act and various congruent state laws by
facilitating and engaging in a horizontal conspiracy to fix the retail price of
e-books.
57
The court also expressed its view that Apple would still be liable
were its behavior subject to a more economics-intensive rule of reason
analysis.
58
Following the ruling on Apple’s liability, the District Court issued a
final injunctive order forbidding the company from enforcing its MFN
clauses with publishers or otherwise retaliating against them for agreeing to
distribution agreements with other retailers, and modifying the terms of its
agency agreements with the publishers.
59
Following the issuance of the
order, Apple and two of the Publisher Defendants—Macmillan and Simon
& Schuster—filed an appeal.
60
III. THE SECOND CIRCUIT’S DECISION
In its appeal before the Second Circuit, Apple contended that its
conduct should not be analyzed under the per se rule. First, Apple argued
that its contracts with publishers were purely vertical and thus outside of the
per se rule’s reach.
61
Second, Apple argued that its conduct warranted
analysis under the rule of reason because of the procompetitive effects on
54. United States v. Apple Inc. (Apple I), 952 F.Supp.2d 638, 645 (S.D.N.Y. 2013).
55. Apple II, 791 F.3d at 322.
56. Id.
57. Id. (citing Apple I, 952 F.Supp.2d at 694).
58. Id. at 312.
59. Id.
60. Id. at 297.
61. Appellant Apple Inc.’s Opening Brief, Apple v. United States, 731 F.3d 290 (2d
Cir. 2015) (2014 WL 3556301), 48–49 (hereinafter Apple’s Opening Brief).
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 889
“enterprise and productivity” realized by its entry into the e-book retail
market.
62
A. WHETHER APPLES RELEVANT CONDUCT WAS HORIZONTAL
OR
VERTICAL
Apple’s opening argument against the application of the per se rule was
that its relations with the publishers consisted of “vertical agreements that
in no way set prices or otherwise limited competition among the
(horizontal) publishers.”
63
Judge Jacobs, dissenting from the Second Circuit
panel’s decision, focused on this distinction and on specific language in
Leegin
64
that he believed mandated rule of reason treatment for such vertical
facilitation.
65
The majority, however, rejected this distinction in light of
other Supreme Court precedent setting forth per se liability for vertically
situated players who participate in and facilitate horizontal price-fixing
conspiracies—so-called “hub-and-spoke” conspiracies.
66
In rejecting the
dissent’s focus on the isolated language in Leegin, the majority noted
Leegin’s susceptibility to multiple interpretations and the general rule
against reading decisions to overrule precedent sub silentio.
67
The majority
concluded that the relevant agreement for the purposes of Section One was
not the contract Apple signed with each publisher, but Apple’s active
agreement to further the horizontal price-fixing conspiracy.
68
It was Apple’s
willing participation in this horizontal scheme that mattered to the court,
not its vertical market position.
69
B. WHETHER APPLES ENTRY JUSTIFIED RULE OF REASON
TREATMENT
Apple alternatively contended that its conduct deserved rule of reason
treatment because it promoted “enterprise and productivity” by introducing
competition into a monopolistic market and fostering technological
62. Id. at 50–52. Apple borrowed the language “enterprise and productivity” from
Seventh Circuit cases built on the legacy of BMI. See, e.g., In re Sulfuric Acid Antitrust
Litig., 703 F.3d 1004, 1011 (7th Cir. 2012).
63. Apple’s Opening Brief, supra note 61, at 49 (emphasis in original).
64. Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 893 (2007)
(“To the extent a vertical agreement setting minimum resale prices is entered upon to
facilitate either type of cartel, it, too, would need to be held unlawful under the rule of
reason.”).
65. Apple II, 791 F.3d at 346.
66. Id. at 322–25.
67. Id. at 324.
68. Id. at 325.
69. Id. at 322.
890 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
innovation. It argued that the theoretical underpinnings of the per se rule
made it appropriate only in cases where conduct “lacked any redeeming
virtue.”
70
Apple then highlighted how its entry had disrupted Amazon’s
total dominance in the e-book retail market, and how the market had since
experienced robust growth.
71
Additionally, it touted the technological
advances the iPad brought as an e-book device over Amazon’s Kindle,
including its ability to display color illustrations and photographs on a
backlit screen.
72
According to Apple, these tangible benefits justified an
exception to the application of the per se rule analogous to the one the
Supreme Court applied in BMI.
73
The Second Circuit majority thoroughly rejected this perspective.
Quickly dismissing Apple’s “technological innovation” argument, the court
pointed out that the iPad’s technological advances were wholly unrelated to
Apple’s agreements with the publishers and that the device was irreversibly
destined for release regardless of whether Apple secured e-book content
deals.
74
The Second Circuit then directed its attention to Apple’s novel “market
entry” argument. It noted that this argument, at base, was “that higher
prices enable more competitors to enter a market,” a theory categorically
inconsistent with antitrust precedent.
75
As regards Apple’s disruption of
Amazon’s e-book monopoly, the court opined that “if Apple could not turn
a profit by selling new releases and bestsellers at $9.99, or if it could not
make the iBookstore and iPad so attractive that consumers would pay more
than $9.99 to buy and read those ebooks on its platform, then there was no
place for its platform in the ebook retail market.”
76
Furthermore, focusing on the district court record, the court found
insufficient support for Apple’s underlying premise that Amazon’s low
prices acted as a barrier to either its own entry or that of other e-book
retailers.
77
Significantly, the majority and dissent sparred over the proper
way to frame Amazon’s role in the e-book market. The majority found that
Amazon pursued a legitimate loss-leadership strategy in selling e-books
below wholesale prices, but the dissent argued that characterization was
70. Apple’s Opening Brief, supra note 61, at 51.
71. Id.
72. Id. at 52.
73. Id.
74. Apple II, 791 F.3d at 335.
75. Id. at 330.
76. Id. at 331.
77. Id. at 332–33.
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 891
unsupported by the facts or the record.
78
While the majority believed
Amazon’s conduct was permissible, they nevertheless concluded that—even
if Amazon had abused its monopoly—“the Sherman Act does not authorize
horizontal price conspiracies as a form of marketplace vigilantism to
eliminate perceived ruinous competition or other competitive evils.”
79
IV. DISCUSSION
This Part will explore specific legal aspects of the Apple decision as well
as its implications for the publishing industry. The first Section considers
whether the Second Circuit correctly applied the per se rule to Apple’s deals
with the publishers. The second Section explores the merits of Apple’s
proposed “market entry” exception to the rule in this situation and in
general. Finally, the third Section discusses the implications the ruling may
have for the publishing industry, and how that industry may react in the
face of ongoing disruption.
A. THE SECOND CIRCUIT CORRECTLY APPLIED EXISTING
ANTITRUST LAW AND PRINCIPLES IN UPHOLDING APPLES PER
SE LIABILITY
The Second Circuit properly interpreted antitrust case law in holding
Apple per se liable for its anticompetitive conduct in the e-books market.
The majority’s decision to apply the per se rule ultimately turned on its view
that Apple’s conduct during its negotiations with the publishers made it a
core participant in the publishers’ horizontal conspiracy and not a complicit
vertical bystander in a hub-and-spoke scheme. In reaching this result, the
Second Circuit drew the critical, yet admittedly subtle, distinction between
a vertically orientated actor’s adoption of restraints to merely facilitate a
horizontal price-fixing conspiracy, and that actor’s direct participation in the
horizontal price-fixing conspiracy.
In Leegin, the Supreme Court acknowledged the potential of vertical
agreements to facilitate horizontal conspiracies among competitors while
overturning the application of the per se rule to vertical minimum price
restraints.
80
The Court specifically recognized that retailers might collude
to decrease output or reduce competition and then “compel a manufacturer
78. Id. at 344. Properly characterizing Amazon’s role in the contemporary e-book
market is critical to understanding the potential long-term impact of Apple’s entry. This
issue will be discussed further, below.
79. Id. at 332 (internal quotation marks omitted).
80. Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 893 (2007).
892 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
to aid the unlawful arrangement with resale price maintenance.”
81
The
Leegin Court then concluded that “[t]o the extent a vertical agreement
setting minimum resale prices is entered upon to facilitate either type of
cartel, it [] would need to be held unlawful under the rule of reason.”
82
Judge
Jacob’s dissent in Apple seized upon this language as transparent guidance
from the high court that Apple’s conduct deserved rule of reason analysis.
83
In support of this position, he noted that the Third Circuit had also read
Leegin to demand rule of reason treatment for vertical restraints alleged to
have been adopted in order to facilitate a horizontal price-fixing
agreement.
84
The Second Circuit majority instead characterized this language in
Leegin as isolated to situations in which horizontal conspirators impose
vertical restraints on non-conspirators.
85
The critical factor, in the majority’s
view, was whether the vertically situated player was a knowing participant
in the underlying horizontal conspiracy. If not, then a given vertical
facilitating practice was entitled to the benefit of the doubt—in the form of
rule of reason treatment—because “it may be difficult to distinguish such
facilitating practices from procompetitive vertical retail price agreements.”
86
In contrast, where a vertical player knowingly participates in and organizes
a hub-and-spoke conspiracy, the majority concluded that the adopted
restraint does not deserve the same benefit of the doubt.
87
The majority’s interpretation of Leegin makes intuitive sense given the
assumptions underlying the differential treatment of horizontal and vertical
restraints. One enduring justification for the per se treatment of horizontal
restraints is that the parties to such agreements, as direct competitors, have
an overwhelming incentive to engage in anticompetitive collusion. Vertical
restraints instead entail agreements between upstream and downstream
players in the same product market where incentives can align to promote
interbrand competition. Had the publishers colluded solely among
themselves, and then demanded the resulting agency agreement and MFN
81. Id.
82. Id.
83. Apple II, 791 F.3d at 346.
84. Id. In Toledo Mack, the Third Circuit read Leegin to mandate that, “rule of reason
analysis applies even when, as in this case, the plaintiff alleges that the purpose of the
vertical agreement between a manufacturer and its dealers is to support illegal horizontal
agreements between multiple dealers.” Toledo Mack Sales & Serv., Inc. v. Mack Trucks,
Inc., 530 F.3d 204, 225 (3d Cir. 2008).
85. Apple II, 791 F.3d at 324–25.
86. Id. at 325.
87. Id.
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 893
clause from Apple, the Second Circuit readily implied that the decision
might have been different.
88
But the majority believed that Apple had
agreed to participate in, and had in fact organized, the horizontal price-
fixing agreement here in exchange for quick and favorable concessions from
the publishers on other terms in their content deals.
89
Once the court
concluded that Apple was actively involved in the horizontal conspiracy,
itself subject to per se condemnation, it would make little sense to provide
the company the benefit of the doubt simply because it helped effectuate its
role through vertical contracts.
The Second Circuit’s decision thus suggests that the critical inquiry in
whether to assign per se liability to a vertically situated actor will be whether
the evidence establishes that it played a culpable role in an underlying
horizontal conspiracy by organizing it or knowingly agreeing to further its
ends. Where a group of horizontal actors “compels” the vertical actor to
facilitate its agreement, Leegin directs rule of reason treatment.
90
Where a
vertical player instead knowingly participates in or organizes such a
horizontal conspiracy, per se treatment attaches—not directly to its
facilitating agreements, but to its underlying agreement to use them to
further the conspiracy. Going forward, this distinction will turn on a
necessarily uncertain line between identifying what facilitation by vertical
actors is “compelled” and what stems from active participation in the
underlying horizontal conspiracy. At base, however, this inquiry simply
entails determining whether the vertical and horizontal actors agreed to
effectuate horizontal price-fixing, which is both a core element in antitrust
cases, and a standard that courts should find workable going forward.
B. ANTITRUST LAW SHOULD NOT RECOGNIZE A “FACILITATING
MARKET ENTRY EXCEPTION TO THE PER SE RULE AGAINST
HORIZONTAL PRICE FIXING
Apple’s additional argument for why it deserved rule of reason treatment
invoked a well-known line of cases, exemplified by BMI, in which courts
have held that otherwise illegal horizontal restraints possessed enough
88. Id. at 323 (“[T]he relevant ‘agreement in restraint of trade’ in this case is not
Apple’s vertical Contracts with the Publisher Defendants (which might well, if challenged,
have to be evaluated under the rule of reason); it is the horizontal agreement that Apple
organized among the Publisher Defendants to raise ebook prices.”).
89. Id. at 334 (“[T]he district court’s fact-finding illustrates that Apple organized the
Publisher Defendants’ price-fixing conspiracy . . . because it was a convenient bargaining
chip.”).
90. Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 893 (2007).
894 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
procompetitive potential to justify application of the rule of reason.
91
Specifically, Apple argued that its agreements with the publishers should
escape per se condemnation because its entry into the retail e-book business
added serious competition to a market overwhelmingly dominated by
Amazon. Given that the per se rule was designed to proscribe conduct that
“lacked any redeeming virtue,” Apple insisted its behavior could not be
squared with the rule.
92
However, Apple’s argument does not fit into the archetype of cases like
BMI, which the Second Circuit properly noted were marked by joint
ventures that were necessary if a given market was to exist at all. After all,
the e-book market existed before Apple’s entry, even if in a concentrated
form. Thus, in order to accept Apple’s argument, a court would need to find
a novel exception to the application of the per se rule: a tall order given the
important judicial efficiency concerns justifying that rule.
93
The implications of Apple’s reasoning are breathtaking. The apparent
result would be that the existence of a monopolist in a given market would
suspend the normal application of the antitrust laws as regards potential
entrants and their conduct in other markets. As a preliminary matter, this
raises serious concerns relating to judicial administrability, as a move to the
rule of reason in such situations would mandate that courts grapple with
economic judgments about the relative merit of competition in one market
versus another. It would also raise tensions with existing monopolization
precedent under Sherman Act Section Two, which recognizes the
legitimacy of certain monopolies and condemns only the inappropriate use
of monopoly power.
94
Finally, even where market entry might counteract
monopolistic abuses, Apple’s argument would essentially require that courts
endorse vigilantism.
91. Apple’s Opening Brief, supra note 61, at 50.
92. Id.
93. For a discussion of this justification, see Leegin, 551 U.S. at 914–17 (Breyer, J.
dissenting).
94. See Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398,
407 (2004). Writing for the majority in Trinko, Justice Scalia noted:
The mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant charging
of monopoly prices, is not only not unlawful; it is an important element
of the free-market system. The opportunity to charge monopoly prices—
at least for a short period—is what attracts “business acumen” in the first
place; it induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic
growth. To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of
monopoly power will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by
an element of anticompetitive conduct.
Id.
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 895
A market entry exception makes little economic or administrative sense.
Where courts have moved away from applying the per se rule to vertical
restraints, they have generally done so in the belief that some ways of
reducing intrabrand competition can have beneficial effects on interbrand
competition.
95
By contrast, Apple’s position would have the court sacrifice
interbrand competition between the publishers for more interbrand
competition between e-book retailers. This tradeoff between increasing
interbrand competition in one market and reducing it in another would
seem to apply in any situation in which Apple’s proposed market-entry
exception would apply. Wherever an entrant’s antitrust violations would be
warranted by the presence of a monopolist in a given market, those
violations—in order to actually promote market entry—would occur in
markets upstream or downstream to the monopolized one.
Further, if rule of reason analysis were to apply to these situations, how
would a court evaluate whether a potential procompetitive effect on a
downstream market outweighs the anticompetitive effect on an upstream
one? The Supreme Court, recognizing the difficulty of such balancing and
the important policy judgments it would entail, has previously characterized
such an undertaking as outside the competency of the courts and more
properly assigned to the legislature.
96
Thus, a divergence from per se
treatment on account of market entry would force courts to engage in a
balancing analysis the Supreme Court has determined courts are
categorically unqualified to handle. This alone is a compelling justification
for maintaining per se treatment in this context.
Additionally, applying a market entry exception to the situation here
would be difficult to reconcile with existing monopolization precedent.
Illegal monopolization under Sherman Act Section Two requires more than
the mere possession of market power; it requires exclusionary acts used to
95. See, e.g., Cont’l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
96. See United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 611–12 (1972). The Court
in Topco noted:
If a decision is to be made to sacrifice competition in one portion of the
economy for greater competition in another portion this [] is a decision
that must be made by Congress and not by private forces or by the courts.
Private forces are too keenly aware of their own interests in making such
decisions and courts are ill-equipped and ill-situated for such
decisionmaking. To analyze, interpret, and evaluate the myriad of
competing interests and the endless data that would surely be brought to
bear on such decisions, and to make the delicate judgment on the relative
values to society of competitive areas of the economy, the judgment of
the elected representatives of the people is required.
Id.
896 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
achieve or maintain that market power.
97
Absent conduct that qualifies as
exclusionary, the Supreme Court has repeatedly emphasized that the
Sherman Act, and the competitive principles it was designed to reinforce,
should not condemn monopoly status alone.
98
Specifically, the Court has
noted that the acquisition of a monopoly through legitimate competition
serves as a valuable reward to those competitors who achieve market
dominance through “growth or development as a consequence of a superior
product, business acumen, or historic accident.”
99
Allowing an entrant to
avoid the full force of the antitrust laws simply based on the existence of a
monopoly in a given market would seem to undercut the view that obtaining
a monopoly can serve as a due reward for successful competitors.
Accordingly, excluding conduct from per se condemnation based on market
entry seems rational only to the extent that entry targets those illicit
monopolies that run afoul of the Sherman Act.
Even where market entry might disrupt an illicit monopoly, creating an
exception to per se treatment on this basis would essentially endorse
competitive vigilantism. Such an exception is contrary to applicable
precedent. The Supreme Court has rejected arguments that the illegal
conduct of others ever justifies antitrust violations.
100
C. APPLES IMPLICATIONS FOR ANTITRUST LAW AS APPLIED TO
THE
PUBLISHING INDUSTRY
The Second Circuit’s decision no doubt came as a great disappointment
to many in the publishing world who view Amazon as a destructive force.
Some commentators were also stunned by the Department of Justice’s initial
decision to pursue charges against Apple and the struggling publishers on
behalf of Amazon.
101
To many, Amazon represents an existential threat to
not just established publishers, but also the very foundations of literary
creativity. They see the major publishing houses as integral to supporting a
vibrant creative infrastructure, and worry that Amazon’s power over the
publishers will erode that infrastructure. This Section examines how the
97. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 at 407.
98. Id.
99. Id.
100. See, e.g., Fashion Originators’ Guild of Am. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 312 U.S. 457,
458 (1941) (noting that illegal conduct by others “would not justify petitioners in
combining together to regulate and restrain interstate commerce in violation of federal
law”).
101. See Keith Gessen, The War of the Words, V
ANITY FAIR (Nov. 30, 2014),
http://www.vanityfair.com/news/business/2014/12/amazon-hachette-ebook-publishing
[https://perma.cc/WED9-SDSG]; see also Charles Schumer, Memo to DOJ: Drop the Apple
E-Books Suit, W
ALL ST. J. (July 17, 2012), http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1000142405
2702303740704577527211023581798 [https://perma.cc/7FY7-3XHB].
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 897
antitrust laws have influenced the current state of the publishing industry,
limiting the ways in which publishers interact with each other and Amazon,
as well as how antitrust laws might shape the publishing industry’s future.
1. The Publishers’ Lack of Bargaining Power or Legal Remedies
Ultimately, the publishers colluded because they individually lacked the
bargaining power necessary to compel Amazon to raise e-book prices. But
the publishers could have legally achieved the same result, by either
adopting agency pricing deals with Amazon so that they could set retail
prices themselves, or simply raising the wholesale price they charged
Amazon such that Amazon had no choice but to increase its retail prices. If
Amazon had simply been an e-book retailer, individual publishers may have
risked its wrath and held firm on their pricing demands. But Amazon held
tremendous leverage over the publishers because it also served as the
dominant physical bookseller.
The publishers also lacked a clear legal recourse. Amazon’s aggressive
leveraging of its market power in its dealings with the publishers was not a
violation of the antitrust laws. The offense of monopolization under
Sherman Act Section Two, as discussed above, requires that a monopolist
engage in exclusionary acts to obtain, protect, or expand its market power.
For the purposes of this analysis, the focus is generally on the monopolist’s
market power in the relevant horizontal market. This means that Amazon’s
exclusionary acts would have to have been targeted toward existing or
potential horizontal competitors in the retail e-book market, rather than
upstream suppliers like the publishers.
102
Thus, under current law, only
Amazon’s exclusion of a potential entrant, like Apple here, could form the
basis for a Section Two claim.
But a Section Two claim is highly unlikely to succeed. The strongest
grounds for a claim that Amazon violated Section Two would have been
that the company engaged in “predatory pricing,” artificially deflating the
sales price of its e-books in order to squeeze its current competitors and
dissuade new ones from entering the retail e-book business. A firm engages
in predatory pricing when it (1) sets its prices below an appropriate measure
102. Amazon was technically a monopsony—a buyer with market power. Notably, the
Supreme Court has never found an illegal monopsony under Sherman Act Section Two.
The closest any company has come to being labeled an illegal monopsony was in
Weyerhaeuser, where the relevant inquiry was whether defendant had engaged in “predatory
bidding” by artificially driving up the cost of upstream inputs in order to deny them to its
competitors. Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U.S. 312,
318–319 (2007). The publishers would have little grounds to make such a claim here, as e-
books are nonrivalrous goods and Amazon was actually driving prices down, not up.
898 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
of its costs, and (2) possesses a dangerous probability of recouping its short-
term losses by eventually leveraging its resulting market power.
103
In this
case, any claim that Amazon was engaging in predatory pricing to exclude
entrants into the e-book market would run into significant obstacles in the
form of alternative explanations for Amazon’s behavior, and the difficulty
of showing that such a scheme could have ever succeeded.
First, Amazon could argue that its pricing strategy represented a
legitimate investment in its e-book sales platform and the Kindle. This
complicates the determination of what the appropriate measure of cost is,
as Amazon could frame the approximately three dollar per unit loss it took
on sales of bestselling e-books as a way to incentivize consumers to purchase
the Kindle and try out the e-book experience. Amazon had a strong
incentive to price e-books below cost in order to drive sales of the Kindle
and to draw new users to its platform.
More definitively, it would be difficult to demonstrate that Amazon ever
had a reasonable chance of recouping its losses because of e-books’ status as
digital goods. In evaluating whether a company has a dangerous probability
of recoupment for the purposes of Section Two, one important variable is
the ease with which a new competitor could subsequently enter the
market.
104
Courts require a dangerous probability of recoupment so as not
to condemn legitimate competitive discounting or unsuccessful attempts at
predation, which simply benefit consumers who enjoy lower prices.
105
Where entry barriers are insignificant, new competitors will enter the
market and punish the predator’s subsequent monopoly pricing. Here, the
ease with which Apple launched the iBookstore illustrates the relatively
insignificant barriers to entry in the retail e-book market. If Amazon
“succeeded” in establishing a complete monopoly in retail e-book sales and
then raised its prices to recoup its losses, little would stop companies with
existing mobile software platforms from entering the market and
undercutting Amazon’s profits with lower priced e-books. Indeed, the
greatest obstacle to entering the retail e-book market would likely be
negotiating content deals with publishers; a group that one would expect to
103. For the purposes of the Sherman Act Section Two, predatory pricing requires a
“dangerous probability” of recoupment. See Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson
Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 224 (1993). Under the Robinson-Patman Act, by contrast,
only a “reasonable prospect” of recoupment need be shown. Id.
104. See id. at 226.
105. See, e.g., Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 224 (noting that “unsuccessful predation is in
general a boon to consumers”); see also Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986) (“[C]utting prices in order to increase business often is the very
essence of competition.”).
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 899
be ever more willing to ease Apple or another competitor’s entry in order to
thwart Amazon.
106
2. The Effect on Consumers
In the end, the Second Circuit’s Apple decision benefitted a company
with tremendous power—Amazon—and harmed smaller players in a
struggling industry. Apple therefore begs the question of whether the
antitrust laws fostered the right result from a consumer welfare perspective.
In order to properly assess the result the court reached in Apple, it is
important to take into account: the state of the publishing industry prior to
Apple’s entry; the publishers’ underlying motivations in raising e-book
prices; whether those motivations align with consumer interests; and
whether Amazon’s conduct actually represents a threat to consumers.
Any potential alignment between the publishers’ and consumers’
interests is merely speculative. As discussed above, Amazon’s pricing
behavior cannot be condemned as a traditional “predatory pricing” scheme,
and thus could not be pigeonholed into existing monopolization precedent.
This reflects the reality that Amazon’s aggressively low priced e-books were
almost surely a boon to consumers, at least in the short-term. The
underlying concern of many in the publishing industry, however, centers on
how Amazon’s pricing might change the literary landscape in the long-
term.
107
The thrust of this concern is that Amazon’s disruption of the
publishing industry could hurt a precariously balanced creative ecosystem.
The theory here is that what could be labeled “inefficiencies” in the
publishing industry actually support a wide creative class of authors, which
yield long term benefits to readers and to society as a whole.
108
The
traditional publisher model involves providing authors advances against
106. Significantly, here the publishers’ apparent concern was not that Amazon would
eventually raise prices above competitive levels, but that it would keep prices low
indefinitely, forever devaluing the book in the consumer’s mind.
107. In the words of Hachette CEO David Young: “The big concern—and it’s a
massive concern—is the $9.99 pricing point. If it’s allowed to take hold in the consumer’s
mind that a book is worth ten bucks, to my mind its game over for this business. Ken
Auletta, Publish or Perish, N
EW YORKER (Apr. 26, 2010), http://www.newyorker.com/
magazine/2010/04/26/publish-or-perish [https://perma.cc/AP7T-H6HD]. The co-owner
of the small publisher Melville House, Dennis Johnson, likewise expressed his fear that
Amazon’s low prices had “successfully fostered the idea that a book is a thing of minimal
value” in consumers’ minds—“It’s a widget.” George Packer, Cheap Words, N
EW YORKER (Feb
17, 2015), http://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2014/02/17/cheap-words [https://perma
.cc/TQ59-VUDM].
108. See Auletta, Publish or Perish, supra note 107 (“Good publishers find and cultivate
writers, some of whom do not initially have much commercial promise. . . . The system is
inefficient, but it supports a class of professional writers, which might not otherwise exist.”).
900 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
future royalties to underwrite their research and writing.
109
Seventy percent
of these advances will never be earned back in full through royalties.
110
A
small number of books will end up selling well, subsidizing the initial
investment in advances to a variety of authors, and insulating those authors
from the vagaries of the market. The worry is that Amazon’s pricing
pressure threatens to disrupt this equilibrium by squeezing margins to the
point where advances are assigned to only those works most likely to earn
them back through robust sales, such as those by already-prominent
authors.
Even assuming that the traditional publishing model provides these
structural creative benefits, it is hard to see how they would fit within the
normal scope of antitrust analysis. Consider the analogous situation of a
horizontal price-fixing conspiracy among manufacturers that increase profit
margins to the point where they are able to provide more jobs, at higher
wages, than they otherwise would be able to.
111
While courts weigh the
procompetitive and anticompetitive effects of a restraint whenever they
engage in rule of reason analysis, at some point the likely effects must
become too speculative to merit consideration. Courts cannot parse every
possible attenuated effect of a restraint. The antitrust laws themselves
promote a particular vision of free-market competition that is itself assumed
to order markets in a desirable manner.
That antitrust law vindicated Amazon’s interests here may also reflect
Amazon’s unique characteristics. Amazon wields its market power in
surprising ways—making it an interesting case study. The company now
controls a sprawling universe of online retail, cloud services, streaming
video, music, and, of course, physical and electronic books. Its success is due
in no small part to its relentless discounting.
112
Despite its apparent power
to raise prices in many goods, it seems not to. As a result, even as it has
grown into a powerful force in the American economy, Amazon has
generally earned relatively paltry overall profits.
113
Furthermore, within the
109. See Ken Auletta, Paper Trail, NEW YORKER (Jun. 25, 2012), http://www
.newyorker.com/magazine/2012/06/25/paper-trail-2 [https://perma.cc/82TR-FBL4].
110. See Auletta, Publish or Perish, supra note 107.
111. This example assumes increased margins find their way to workers and not
investors. In the publishing industry, commentators have widely differing views on whether
profits have ever been sufficiently channeled toward authors.
112. Amazon even markets itself as “Earth’s most consumer-centric company.See
Packer, supra note 107.
113. See Farhad Manjoo, How Amazon’s Long Game Yielded a Retail Juggernaut, N.Y.
TIMES (Nov. 18, 2015), http://www.nytimes.com/2015/11/19/technology/how-amazons
-long-game-yielded-a-retail-juggernaut.html [https://perma.cc/6P78-NKKC].
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 901
company, more profitable divisions such as its cloud storage business
actually subsidize investment in other, less profitable ones.
114
If the goal of antitrust law was merely to promote competition between
firms in a given market, it may actually be preferable for a monopolist like
Amazon to charge a price higher than the market would normally support.
Such a “supracompetitive” price is the carrot that incentivizes other firms to
enter, eventually hastening the monopolist’s downfall. What is to be done
with a company that continuously accumulates market power but refuses to
leverage it against consumers? Does this even pose a problem? A cynical
long-view perspective is that such a company will continue to make
investments that allow it to operate so efficiently, or take advantage of
platform effects so successfully, that no entrant would ever be able to
undercut its prices. Once a company has achieved that level of dominance,
the company may then raise prices without fear that new firms would
attempt to enter the market.
3. Implications for the Publishing Industry
The conflict between Amazon and the publishers reflects a familiar
trend. As digital technologies stir an established content market—like
music and television before e-books—conflict between newly ascendant
digital players like Amazon and traditional gatekeepers is almost inevitable.
And Amazon’s preexisting market power in physical books only exacerbated
the tension between Amazon and publishers. The publishing industry is
likely to face ongoing changes as it acclimates to both the new normal of
Amazon’s physical dominance, and the rise of the e-book.
One seemingly inevitable result of Amazon’s dominance and the
disruptive emergence of the e-book market is greater consolidation in the
publishing industry. Since the initial district court decision in United States
v. Apple, the trend toward consolidation in the publishing world has only
accelerated. In 2013, Penguin and Random House—two of the former “Big
Six” publishers—merged to form Penguin Random House, creating by far
114. Deutsche Bank estimates that Amazon’s cloud service could soon be worth $160
billion as a stand-alone company. Id. That division maintains a net operating margin of 25
percent, compared to 3.5 percent for Amazon’s North American retail business. Id. For
more details on Amazon’s business model, see Andrea M. Hall, Standing the Test of Time:
Likelihood of Confusion in Multi Time Machine v. Amazon, 31 B
ERKELEY TECH. L.J. 815,
826–29 (2016).
902 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
the largest publishing house in the world.
115
The merger was widely seen as
a bid to increase bargaining power with Amazon.
116
This sort of consolidation poses its own threats to competition and
creative output at the publisher level. Large publishing houses generally
maintain many “imprint” subsidiary publishing brands united under the
larger corporate umbrella. Predictably, the large firms restrict their imprints
from bidding against each other for manuscripts, which means that mergers
effectively reduce the relative bargaining power of authors by winnowing
competition for manuscripts.
117
In this way consolidation can pass along the
pressure publishers feel from Amazon to authors, with the potential to
disrupt the creative ecosystem.
While the publishers consolidate and authors are left with ever fewer
traditional suitors, Amazon itself has pursued a strategy that represents an
existential threat to the publishers: disintermediation.
118
Amazon
Publishing, created after the Kindle’s release, offers an increasingly popular
self-publishing tool for those who either fail to secure deals with publishers
or who covet the opportunity to earn up to seventy percent of their work’s
royalties.
119
But Amazon has experienced a rocky start in promoting the self-
publishing model thus far. Established authors have proven surprisingly
loyal to their publishers and new authors may be drawn towards the aura of
prestige surrounding certain traditional publishing house brands.
120
Amazon’s early failures with this model have been attributed both to tension
between Amazon and other physical retailers, as well as a lack of
institutional knowledge on Amazon’s part—the industry frequently casts
Amazon as a data-driven company out of its element in a business built on
relationships.
121
Nevertheless, Amazon’s efforts in this area continue.
115. See Jeremy Greenfield, Penguin Random House Merger Deal Closed, New Publishing
Giant Emerges, D
IGITAL BOOK WORLD (July 1, 2013), http://www.digitalbookworld
.com/2013/penguin-random-house-merger-deal-closed-new-publishing-giant-emerges
[https://perma.cc/6C8K-T3AF].
116. See Packer, supra note 107.
117. See Boris Kachka, Book Publisher’s Big Gamble, N.Y.
TIMES (July 9, 2013), http://www
.nytimes.com/2013/07/10/opinion/book-publishings-big-gamble.html [https://perma.cc/
H9KT-CDK5].
118. Disintermediation refers to any process by which a firm bypasses an intermediary
between itself and end consumers. Amazon has taken steps toward working directly with
authors, cutting the traditional publishers out of the process. See Packer, supra note 107.
119. See Packer, supra note 107.
120. See id. Notably, MacKenzie Bezos, the wife of Amazon CEO Jeff Bezos,
published her 2014 novel Traps with Knopf, a respected imprint that is now a subsidiary
of Penguin Random House. Id.
121. Id.
2016] E-BOOK ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 903
The Second Circuit’s decision represents a win for Amazon’s—and
consumers’—interests. However, focusing solely on the legal result obscures
how Apple and the publishers ultimately achieved their objectives of raising
prices and breaking Amazon’s hold on the e-book retail market. After the
expiration of the waiting period imposed as part of their settlement with the
Justice Department, the five publishing houses that had reached deals with
Apple eventually had to negotiate new deals with Amazon. This led to a
highly publicized standoff during the negotiations between Amazon and
Hachette—the first of the publishers to renegotiate.
122
In the deals that
followed, every publisher insisted upon and received the power to set prices
under the agency model.
123
Since those deals were negotiated, e-book prices
have risen, and—perhaps not coincidently—growth in e-book sales has
begun to level off.
124
Furthermore, Amazon now faces considerable
competition in the retail e-book market from both Apple and Google.
On March 7, 2016 the Supreme Court denied Apple’s cert petition.
125
Notably, the $450 million the company has agreed to pay out as a result of
the case represents a small sum compared to its latest quarterly profits of
almost $11.1 billion.
126
V. CONCLUSION
The Second Circuit’s decision in Apple is a well-reasoned application of
existing antitrust precedent and principles. Apple’s justifications for why its
conduct deserved rule of reason, as opposed to per se analysis, do not make
sense given either the facts of the case or established antitrust approaches.
Once the court determined that Apple had knowingly participated in the
publishers’ horizontal pricing fixing conspiracy, the fact that Apple used
vertical contracts in order to effectuate that conspiracy should not save it
122. See Davey Alba, Amazon Resolves Dispute With Top-Five Publisher Hachette Over
Book Sales, W
IRED (Nov. 13, 2014), http://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-hachette-end
-publishing-dispute-1415898013 [https://perma.cc/VN8E-N7UC].
123. See Alison Griswold, Amazon to Publishers: Set Your Own E-Book Prices! Amazon
to Customers: Not Our Fault!, S
LATE (Apr. 14, 2015), http://www.slate.com/blogs/
moneybox/2015/04/14/what_the_amazon_harpercollins_deal_means_for_e_book_pricing
_and_publishing.html [https://perma.cc/F5V2-MNVW].
124. See Jeffrey A. Trachtenberg, E-Book Sales Fall After New Amazon Contracts, W
ALL
ST. J. (Sept. 3, 2015), http://www.wsj.com/articles/e-book-sales-weaken-amid-higher
-prices-1441307826 [https://perma.cc/95HX-CW2R].
125. See Adam Liptak & Vindu Goel, Supreme Court Declines to Hear Apple’s Appeal in
E-Book Pricing Case, N.Y.
TIMES (Mar. 7, 2016), http://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/08/
technology/apple-supreme-court-ebook-prices.html [https://perma.cc/3FNW-Y22W].
126. See Colin Lecher, Apple Will Pay $450 Million After Losing Ebooks Price-fixing
Appeal, T
HE VERGE (June 30, 2015), http://www.theverge.com/2015/6/30/8870061/
apple-450-million-ebooks-price-fixing-appeal [https://perma.cc/HNP7-792S].
904 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 31:AR
from the application of the per se rule. Rule of reason treatment represents
an unnecessary benefit of the doubt in such situations.
The court likewise properly rejected the invitation to recognize a market
entry exception to the per se rule. Such a rule would require courts to make
sweeping decisions about the relative value of competition in different
markets, would fly in the face of monopolization precedent, and essentially
endorse antitrust vigilantism.
In the end, the circumstances surrounding the Apple decision also
provide an insight into the current state of the publishing industry and how
antitrust law might affect its future. The industry is currently in the midst
of an ongoing transformation driven by technology and embodied by
Amazon—a highly disruptive force. Antitrust law will not insulate the
publishers from this change, nor will it ignore their collusion. While
publishers ultimately succeeded in raising e-book prices and slowing the
pace of change, the future of the publishing business is far from clear. In the
words of Jeff Bezos, Amazon’s CEO: “Amazon is not happening to
bookselling. The future is happening to bookselling.”
127
127. See Packer, supra note 107.