Marshall-Wythe School of Law
A CAREFUL EXAMINATION OF THE PROPOSED LIVE NATION-
T
ICKETMASTER MERGER
Alan J. Meese
William & Mary Law School
Barak D. Richman
Duke University School of Law
William & Mary Law School Research Paper No. 09-41
This paper can be downloaded without charge from
the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
http://ssrn.com/abstract
= 1542626
A Careful Examination of the
Proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster Merger
. eese
*
Barak D. Richman
**
th. They deserve honesty. The
best music, you can seek some shelter in it momentarily, but it's essentially
with.
God have mercy on the man who doubts what he's sure of.
“Brilliant Disguise”
n the popular
een asked as
erger of Live Nation and Ticketmaster, and
we do so with the objectivity and honesty called for by The Boss’s quotes above. The
whether the
ation are two
t the merged
petitive. We
ing industry.
try, and along
res based on
a competitive
kets to their own events and can thus easily forgo
ibution is an
ely that even
a monopolist provider of fully outsourced ticketing services could exercise market power.
Ultimately, a proper assessment of the horizontal effects of this merger would have to
The second category of arguments by critics opposing the merger rests on claims that
vertical aspects of the transaction would produce anticompetitive effects. Indeed,
Alan J M
People deserve better. They deserve the tru
there to provide you something to face the world
gsteen--Bruce Sprin
Tunnel of Love (1987)
As great admirers of The Boss and as fans of live entertainment, we share i
dismay over rising ticket prices for live performances. But we have b
antitrust scholars to examine the proposed m
proposed merger has been the target of aggressive attacks from several industry
commentators and popular figures, but the legal and policy question is
transaction is at odds with the nation’s antitrust laws.
One primary source of concern to critics is that Ticketmaster and Live N
leading providers of ticket distribution services, and these critics argue tha
entity would have a combined market share that is presumptively anticom
observe, however, that this transaction is taking place within a rapidly chang
The spread of Internet technologies has transformed the entertainment indus
with it the ticket distribution business such that a reliance on market sha
historical sales is misleading. A growing number of venues, aided by
bidding process that creates moments of focused competition, can now acquire the
requisite capabilities to distribute tic
reliance upon providers of outsourced distribution services. If self-distr
available and attractive option for venues, as it appears to be, then it is unlik
weigh heavily the emerging role of Internet technologies in this dynamic business and the
industry-wide trend towards self-distribution.
*
Ball Professor of Law, William and Mary, ajmees@wm.edu
**
Professor of Law and Business Administration, Duke University, richm[email protected]
, and thus the
ement among
competitive
of academic
our vantage
the proposed
at the merger
downstream
a number of
ry, are likely
erger and would be unlikely but for the
companies’ integration. For these reasons, we submit this analysis in an effort to inform
the debate with current economic and legal scholarship.
Ticketmaster’s and Live Nation’s core businesses are in successive markets
proposed transaction is primarily a vertical merger, but there is broad agre
economists and antitrust authorities that vertical mergers rarely introduce
concerns and are usually driven by efficiency motivations. This wealth
scholarship, which is reflected in current antitrust law, has not—from
point—been properly incorporated into the public dialogue concerning
merger. To the contrary, critics articulate concerns, including the fears th
would lead to the leveraging of market power and the foreclosure of
competition, that are refuted by accepted scholarship. Moreover, there are
specific efficiencies that, consistent with economic and organizational theo
to emerge from a Live Nation-Ticketmaster m
A Careful Examination of the
Proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster Merger
Meese
Barak D. Richman
...................
.................... 1
.. 5
..................
..................
II .................
..................
.................. 5
...................
.................. 8
.................. 3
..................
..................
................... 5
.................. 9
....
n..............
..................
..................
IV ..................
.................
..................
..................
.................. 4
et
.................. 6
...................
4. Industry-wide Vertical Integration.......................................................................102
Addressing Critics of the Live Nation-Ticketmaster Transaction .............................. 105
1. Leveraging Market Power from Ticket Distribution to Concert Promotion........107
2. Foreclosing Competition in Ticket Distribution..................................................111
Summary ..................................................................................................................... 116
V. Conclusion ................................................................................................................ 117
Alan J.
Executive Summary.................................................................................... ...
..
....
...
....
...
...
....
...
....
s.
...
...
...
tit
Horizontal Efficiencies Resulting from the Merger....................................
... 79
....
....
....
.....
.....
Ma
.....
......
.. ii
I. Introduction ............................................................................................ ..
II. Background on Live Entertainment: Industry Structure and Trends ............................ 5
Overview .......................................................................................................................
Parties to Proposed Merger................................................................... . 13
Recent Industry Developments............................................................... .. 18
I. Analysis of Merger’s Horizontal Consequences................................ .. 23
Market Definition................................................................................... ..
.2
25
1. General Standards Governing Market Definition......................... ..
272. Identification of Relevant Consumers .......................................... .
.23. Geographic and Product Markets.................................................. ..
34. Applying the SSNIP Test.............................................................. ..
Identification of Market Participants and Calculation of Market Share .
53
44
Potential Adverse Effects ....................................................................... ..
51. Coordinated Interaction ................................................................ ..
.52. Unilateral Effects .......................................................................... ..
Entry.......................................................................................................................... 64
Concerns About a Purported Loss of “Future” or “Potential” Compe io 69
78
Summary ................................................................................................ ..
80. Analysis of Merger’s Vertical Consequences..................................... .
The Evolving Economic and Legal Treatment of Vertical Integration.. ..
81
Scrutiny of Ticketmaster’s Vertical Agreements................................... .. 88
Efficiencies from Vertical Integration ................................................. .. 93
1. Investments in Promotion and Information .................................. . .9
2. Cooperative Adaptation to Meet Artists’ Demands, Respond to rk
.9Changes, & Pursue Innovations................................................... ..
3. Targeted Linkages Between Venues, Entertainers, and Fans...... . 99
Executive Summary
ment, Inc.
ment. The proposed
changing
Internet
technologies and respond to disruptions to previously reliable revenue flows. The
er the merger is
us to examine the
ences of the merger in light of public criticism. Our
ana is based
Live Nation and Ticketmaster both provide multiple services that contribute to the
tion and
related
operates.
arketing company,
sells tickets in the primary and secondary markets, licenses technology that facilitates the
self-distribution of tickets for assorted venues, and manages entertainment talent.
Because Live Nation’s primary business is in live entertainment promotion and
Ticketmaster’s primary business is in primary ticket sales distribution, the proposed
transaction is chiefly a vertical merger and leads to the integration of successive stages in
On February 10, 2009, Live Nation, Inc. and Ticketmaster Entertain
announced their intentions to merge and create Live Nation Entertain
merger is one of several recent and significant developments in a rapidly
industry, and it reflects the search for new business models that capitalize on
Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division has been investigating wheth
permissible under the nation’s antitrust laws, and the parties have asked
legality and competitive consequ
lysis reflects our own views, not those of the parties or their counsel, and
only on publicly available information.
production of live entertainment. Live Nation, the world’s largest producer of live
concerts, engages in the promotion of concerts and other events, the opera
management of live entertainment venues, various forms of entertainment-
merchandising, and the sale of tickets for events at venues it owns or
Ticketmaster, the world’s leading live entertainment ticketing and m
ii
the value chain for producing and delivering live entertainment. Economic theory
rmissive approach to
cket sales
poised to
which it has
no affiliation. We therefore examine both the horizontal and the vertical consequences
w a Live Nation-
n. Following
arket
kelihood of any
coordinated or unilateral adverse effects caused by the merger; any potential competition
y the merger.
Our m
he principal
vant market
itory price
. Many enter
d agents, but an
tegies, in which
lf-distribute tickets to the events they host. Some pursue vertical
integration strategies by developing in-house technology to self-distribute
tickets, and some purchase “enabling” technology and services from ticketing
technology companies that support ticket self-distribution. This “enabling”
option has become increasingly common, indicating that the technology
underlying Internet ticketing has become widespread and has measurably
contributed to major organizational changes in the marketing of live
entertainment.
instructs that such vertical arrangements are usually motivated by efficiency
considerations, and antitrust law accordingly has adopted a very pe
such mergers. Nonetheless, Live Nation is also engaged in primary ti
(primarily for venues it owns or operates), and some have argued that it is
compete vigorously with Ticketmaster to distribute tickets for venues with
of the transaction.
Horizontal Analysis. Our horizontal analysis focuses on ho
Ticketmaster merger would impact the market for primary ticket distributio
the Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, it includes a discussion of m
definition, market participants, and approximation of market shares; the li
that is foreclosed by the merger; and any horizontal efficiencies created b
ain conclusions are as follows:
x Venues (rather than ticket purchasers, i.e., concert-goers) are t
purchasers of ticket distribution services. Defining the rele
requires evaluating how venues would respond to a non-trans
increase by providers of these services.
x Venues pursue many different methods of distributing tickets
into contracts with ticket distributors that serve as outsource
increasing number have pursued vertical integration stra
venues se
iii
x Many venues consider vertical integration to be a reasona
outsourced ticket distribution. If self-distribution technology i
available, then venues would self-distribute in response to a s
increase by a hypothetical monopolist of outsourced ticket dis
services. Thus, a critical question in evaluating the competitiv
proposed merger—one that overrides the significance of calcula
shares and most other determinations required by the merger g
whether the ease and attractiveness of self-distribution strategi
any possibility of supracompetitive pricing. For this reason, cr
proposed merger
ble substitute for
s widely
ignificant price
tribution
eness of the
ting market
uidelines—is
es would offset
iticism of the
that rests on the parties’ historical market shares fails to
likely to accurately
f ticket
itigate the
g remaining
t venues
adopt when ticket distribution contracts expire creates moments of focused
can increase
participants appears
so require a
If self-
s many providers
teral increase in
rs have responded to
nt invitations by venues for bids to provide or support ticket distribution
ipants have the
o a merged
storical market
distribution
he ticket distribution
stribute and tailor
gies for venues, such as Veritix, or from large
venue operators and promoters, such as AEG. These firms are at least as
likely to sustain a competitive threat to the merged company as Live Nation
was to pose a threat to Ticketmaster if the merger were not consummated.
Moreover, if enablement technologies have become as attractive and
widespread as they appear to be, then the ready availability of these
technologies could alone deter a merged Live Nation-Ticketmaster from
charging supracompetitive prices.
recognize the market’s technological dynamism and is un
identify market power.
x The widespread possibility of self-distribution, heterogeneity o
distribution contracts, and concealment of contractual terms m
likelihood that the merger would encourage any collusion amon
market competitors. Moreover, the competitive bidding process tha
competition in which outsiders can gain entry and small firms
market share, with the result that collusion among market
unlikely.
x An analysis of the merger’s unilateral competitive effects will al
determination of the attractiveness and ease of self-distribution.
distribution technology is widely available, then the market’
of enabling technology would promptly respond to any unila
price by the merged entity. A number of assorted provide
rece
services. These experiences suggest that current market partic
capabilities to meet the needs of venues that seek alternatives t
Live Nation Entertainment. It additionally confirms that hi
sales belie the current level of competitiveness in the ticket
market.
x Competitive entry into, and competitive expansion in, t
market could either come from the many companies that di
Internet ticketing technolo
iv
x It is possible that horizontal efficiencies could result from the
merger, perhaps if one company can provide ticket distr
lower cost than the other, but we have not encounter
proposed
ibution services at a
ed any evidence
suggesting that horizontal efficiencies will be more than modest.
legal scholars
erally reflect
rtical elements of
the proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger therefore suggest that many efficiency
motivations underlie the transaction. Nonetheless, critics of the proposed Live Nation-
nents of the
ecades ago, when
ost vertical
theory have
revealed deep flaws in those suspicions. Current antitrust law has evolved accordingly,
becoming much more accepting of vertical mergers, and nearly all such transactions
rs also have the
ry and
ggest that the
x Investments in promotion and information
Vertical Analysis. There is broad consensus among economists and
that vertical mergers only very rarely pose competitive risks and instead gen
procompetitive efforts to minimize transaction costs. The substantial ve
Ticketmaster merger persist in expressing opposition to vertical compo
merger. Such criticisms were common in antitrust decisions several d
the “inhospitality tradition” directed antitrust policy to be suspicious of m
arrangements, including vertical integration, but advances in economic
survive antitrust scrutiny.
In addition to posing little risk of competitive harm, vertical merge
potential to generate many efficiencies that would be unattainable through contractual or
market organization. Recent developments in the live entertainment indust
statements made the management of both Live Nation and Ticketmaster su
proposed merger has the potential to generate the following efficiencies:
. Internet technologies have
presented lucrative opportunities to generate new content, consumer data, and
promotional strategies for fans of live entertainment. Creating the platforms
for these strategies, however, requires investments that are difficult to specify
and monitor by contract. When activities such as these are hard to observe
and are therefore noncontractible, yet are important in creating value, vertical
v
integration is a common efficiency response. Vertical integrat
could help providers of live entertainment invest in promo
to reduce exces
ion strategies
tion (for example,
s capacity in concerts) and develop Internet content and
marketing strategies.
x Meeting Artist Demands and Market Changes
. The Wall Stree
described the world of live entertainment as “an industry underg
shifts.” Adjusting to a changing market environment is addition
when different players contribute at each stage in the value ch
hallmarks of vertical integration, however, is the ability to p
adaptation. Vertically integrated strategies such as the L
t Journal has
oing seismic
ally difficult
ain. One of the
ursue cooperative
ive Nation-
nize the
odel.
Ticketmaster merger could facilitate innovations that would orga
assorted inputs to live entertainment into an effective business m
x Linking Venues, Entertainers, and Fans.
The many market seg
to produce live entertainment in today’s mostly non-integrated in
distance between artists and their fans, and establishing direct l
between artists and fans is perhaps the most oft-stated justificati
Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger. One of the attributes of v
is the ability to facilitate the sharing of knowledge. It is
artists and
ments required
dustry create
inkages
on for the
ertical integration
thus no surprise that
venues are seeking vertically integrated mechanisms to
tes the creation
for better
t and
merchandise.
Efficiencies such as thes aster merger,
d towards vertical
rged entity would
and that the
merged entity would leverage its market power in one market for anticompetitive gain in
the other. We conclude that neither available evidence nor economic theory support
these fears. To be sure, the merged company would contribute to the changing face of
the live entertainment industry, and industry players will need to continue searching for
innovative business models. But the merger does not change market concentration or
communicate with fans. Moreover, vertical integration facilita
and dissemination of information that could serve as a platform
artist-fan communication and the marketing of additional conten
e are likely to follow from a Live Nation-Ticketm
and we suspect that they also account for the broader industry-wide tren
integration.
Critics of the proposed merger have expressed fears that the me
foreclose entry in both the ticket distribution and the promotion markets,
vi
vii
entry possibilities in the promotion market, and we suspect that the spread of Internet
arket power
s competitive
r to be procompetitive adaptations that the
antitrust laws should encourage and not condemn.
technologies has greatly removed the possibility of obtaining or leveraging m
in the ticket distribution market. To the degree that the merger generate
advantages to the merged firm, these appea
I. Introduction
ent, Inc.
ent. This “merger
tion services and live
ve
about their
ability to compete with Live Nation Entertainment, and public figures—including Bruce
Springsteen, a particular favorite to one of the instant authors—have decried the
tion was
On February 10, 2009, Live Nation, Inc. and Ticketmaster Entertainm
announced their intentions to merge and create Live Nation Entertainm
of equals” would combine the nation’s leaders in ticket distribu
entertainment promotion, creating by all accounts an industry leader in li
entertainment.
1
Not surprisingly, smaller competitors have raised concerns
2
economic and artistic consequences of such a combination.
3
Political atten
1
Press Release, Live Nation and Ticketmaster Entertainment to Combine in Merger of
Equals to Create World's Premier Live Entertainment Company (Feb. 10,
available at
2009),
&terms= (last
r Consumers
Antitrust,
y, 111th Cong.
z, Co-Owner
z Testimony];
tection, Industry
on, http://www.
tion Merger,
/02/04/bruce-
visited Sept. 9,
ans stating that
as furious as it has
ket situation even
worse for the fan than it is now would be Ticketmaster and Live Nation coming up with a
single system, thereby returning us to a near monopoly situation in music ticketing.”).
Joel Rose, Ticketmaster, Live Nation Merger Investigated, NPR, Feb. 12, 2009,
http://www.npr.org/templates/story/story.php?storyId =100616154 (last visited Sept. 9,
2009) (reporting statement by Senator Charles Schumer, following the Live Nation-
Ticketmaster merger announcement, that , “[t]he last thing we should do is give
Ticketmaster more influence… If these two entities were to merge, control of concert
http://mediacenter.ticketmaster.com/Extranet/
TMPRArticlePressReleases.aspx?id=8080&fragment=0&SearchType=OR
visited Sept. 9, 2009).
2
See, e.g., The Ticketmaster/Live Nation Merger: What Does it Mean fo
and the Future of the Concert Business: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on
Competition Policy and Consumer Rights of the S. Comm. on the Judiciar
(2009) (written testimony of Jerry Mickelson, Chairman and Executive Vice President of
Jam Productions, Ltd. [hereinafter Mickelson Testimony] and Seth Hurwit
of I.M.P. Productions and 9:30 Club Washington, D.C. [hereinafter Hurwit
National Association of Ticket Brokers, Press Release – Consumer Pro
Groups Joint Statement on Ticketmaster/Live Nation Merger Investigati
natb.org/MediaCenter/index.cfm?article=42.
3
See Bruce Springsteen "Furious" at Ticketmaster, Rails Against Live Na
ROLLING STONE, http://www.rollingstone.com/rockdaily/index.php/2009
springsteen-furious-at-ticketmaster-rails-against-live-nation-merger/ (last
2009) (publishing letter from Bruce Springsteen and his tour team to f
“[t]he abuse of our fans and our trust by Ticketmaster has made us
made many of you . . . . [T]he one thing that would make the current tic
1
recently directed at the proposed merger as Senator Herb Kohl, Chairman of the Senate
tant
arney requesting the Antitrust Division to scrutinize the
mer
mon refrain in
esigned to
achieve. The Sherman and Clayton Acts “were enacted for the protection of competition,
5
irable conduct. As
y the parties to
rger. We
iting in our capacity
as experts in antitrust law and policy, and we are presenting only our own views and not
those of the parties or their counsel. We accordingly apply our analysis relying on
publicly available information and our understanding of the legal and economic
Subcommittee on Antitrust, and Congressman Bill Pascrell each sent letters to Assis
Attorney General Christine V
ger with skepticism and care.
4
Although such popular backlash against economic giants is a com
American antitrust law, these concerns do not reflect what antitrust law is d
not competitors,” and it is not uncommon for certain resentments and intuitions to
channel anger at what actually is procompetitive and economically des
scholars of antitrust law and institutional economics, we have been asked b
examine the legality and the competitive consequences of the proposed me
should state upfront that, while we are being compensated, we are wr
methodologies that guide merger analysis in the U.S.
by one
, having profound and far-reaching implication for consumers, promoters and
, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Competition
Policy and Consumer Rights to Christine Varney, Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust
Division, United States Dep’t of Justice (July 27, 2009) [hereinafter Kohl Letter]; Letter
from Congressman Bill Pascrell, et. al to Christine A. Varney, Assistant Attorney
General, Antitrust Division, United States Dep’t of Justice (July 27, 2009) [hereinafter
Pascrell Letter].
5
See Cargill Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, 479 U.S. 104, 115 (1986); Brunswick Corp.
v. Pueblo Bowl-o-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488 (1977).
venues and representation of artists in those venues would be controlled
organization
artists alike.”).
4
Letter from Senator Herb Kohl, Chairman
2
This memorandum first describes the industry structure and emerging trends and
petition. We
nment are
undergoing
ndscape that the
ation, wherein
creators of live entertainment are generating efficiencies and valuable new markets by
ution business,
the proposed
competition.
d proceeding
through calculation (or approximation) of market shares, assessment of possible adverse
effects, prospect of post-merger entry, and consideration of horizontal efficiencies. The
til recently
iewing
vertical integration
on into
Ticketmaster’s use of exclusive contracts. We then discuss the potential for merger-
specific efficiencies and assess arguments made by some of the merger’s critics,
including Senator Kohl and Congressman Pascrell, who have warned that the merger may
have anticompetitive consequences.
then assesses the merger’s likely horizontal and vertical impact on com
observe that both ticket distribution and the entire business of live entertai
technologically dynamic and rapidly evolving industries, and each has been
substantial structural changes in recent years. It is within this changing la
proposed merger reflects a broader industry trend towards vertical integr
interacting directly with fans.
Because Ticketmaster and Live Nation are both in the ticket distrib
with Live Nation having recently entered, there is a horizontal element to
merger, requiring analysis of how it might affect both actual and potential
We conduct a full horizontal analysis, beginning with market definition an
merger also has vertical dimensions, with Live Nation having been un
Ticketmaster’s largest client. We begin a vertical examination by rev
developments in institutional economics and antitrust law regarding
and briefly review the results of an earlier Department of Justice investigati
3
We do not have access to the same confidential information possessed by the
elieve that a Live
commonly
ribute tickets is
emerged
with platforms that can cater to clients’ specific needs, that there is a competitive bidding
at an increasing
this rapid
bution
likely do not
f market power.
A proper determination of the merger’s horizontal competitive consequences instead
rests, above all, on how easily venues can pursue self-distribution strategies and how
ternatives to a
Although the results of this dispassionate antitrust analysis might be more
supportive of the merger than many critics would hope, we offer this analysis echoing the
Boss’s admonition to seek truth and maintain an appropriate amount of self-doubt.
enforcement agencies or the parties. Our information is thus incomplete and our
conclusions can only be preliminary. Nonetheless, we find reason to b
Nation-Ticketmaster merger is likely to produce certain efficiencies that
accompany vertical integration. We observe that the technology to dist
becoming increasingly widespread, that several technology companies have
process in which these offerings are presented to potential clients, and th
number of venues are now pursuing self-distribution strategies. Given
emergence of new technologies and the evident attractiveness of self-distri
strategies, concentration calculations based on historical market shares
accurately reflect the transaction’s propensity to facilitate the exercise o
many providers of ticket distribution services would be available to offer al
merged Live Nation and Ticketmaster.
4
6
II. Background on Live Entertainment: Industry Structure and Trends
Overview
llion in ticket
enerated by
bits, and other
ent industry
also rely on revenue from ancillary products, such as sales of merchandise, concessions,
ing increasingly vertically integrated, most
con umber of different
business
needs, and many of these managers further contract with booking agents to arrange an
agreement with a promoter for individual performances or a tour. The promoter is then
responsible for securing a venue for the performances, and the venue is accompanied by
ip, and band-
h ticket
The market for live entertainment events generated roughly $21 bi
sales in 2007, with $14.3 billion generated by sporting events, $6.7 billion g
concerts, and a small remainder generated by theatre performances, art exhi
events that utilized ticketing services.
7
Participants in the live entertainm
and music. Although the industry is becom
certs and performances require contractual arrangements among a n
and otherwise independent parties.
Artists contract with promoters to arrange live concert performances. Artists
often contract through a manager that handles the artists’ performance and
other revenue-producing services such as parking, concessions, sponsorsh
related merchandise. The venue, or sometimes the promoter, contracts wit
6
This section relies heavily on Krueger, infra note 9, and Barclays Cap
70.
7
The Potential Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed Combination o
Entertainm
ital, infra note
f Ticketmaster
ent Inc. and Live Nation, Inc., Hearing on Competition in the Ticketing and
Promotion Industry Before the Subcomm. on Courts and Competition Policy of the
House Comm. on the Judiciary, 111 Cong. 7-8 (2009) [hereinafter Doyle Testimony]
(written testimony of Robert W. Doyle, Jr., Partner, Doyle, Barlow & Mazard, PLLC).
Secondary ticket sales, which for 2007 totaled $2.6 billion, are brokered by agents who
purchase performance tickets from the primary sales agents or initial purchasers and then
resell to end-consumers either with a mark-up above the sales price or through auction
mechanisms.
5
distributors that administer ticket sales to performances through Internet, retail, telephone
and box offi
oters have
ey allocate serial
ments vary
oters, and other
circumstances, the typical contract distributes the revenue generated by concert tours
r a
t for the venue,
itional revenues
with the band
typically recovering around 85%. These contracts allocate other revenues as well, with
the band typically receiving revenue from merchandise sales and the venue receiving
ented with
tist a lump sum
ual revenues,
8
but
contracts divide such residual revenue between promoters and artists. This means
that promoters and artists tend to share (though not equally) the economic risks and
n venues are
unfilled.
ce sales.
Contracts between artists (via their managers and agents) and prom
been likened to book contracts between authors and publishers in that th
revenues and often involve upfront payments. Although contractual agree
significantly based on the popularity of the band, the record of the prom
sequentially. The first-dollar revenues generated by the performances go to the band in a
“guaranteed advance,” and then subsequent revenue secures for the promote
“guaranteed profit,” which includes expenses (including advertising, ren
labor, etc) and a negotiated profit. The promoter and band then share add
(if any) that exceed both the guaranteed advance and guaranteed profit,
revenue from parking and concessions. Live Nation has recently experim
some “360” contracts with certain marquee performers that give the ar
guarantee for an entire tour, with Live Nation recovering all of the resid
most
benefits of ticketed performances, and both suffer from lost revenue whe
8
Ethan Smith, Deal to Rock Music Industry, WALL ST. J., Feb. 5, 2009, at B10.
Record labels, such as Warner Music Group and Sony Music Entertainment have also
experimented with 360 deals, though with lesser-known artists. Id.
6
The contracts between artists and promoters also set the face value of concert
nflation over the
prices on a
arket is evidence
s explanations for
such underpricing), but others describe the secondary market as a more flexible
11
arying
cterizations of the secondary market, with different characterizations offering
alte y market
Many venues and promoters contract with ticket distribution service companies,
such as Ticketmaster, to handle all their ticketing needs. These contracts tend to be
ervices for a
of time in exchange for the right to charge service fees that are
tickets—i.e., the price of the ticket excluding any service fees, credit card fees, or taxes.
Although face value ticket prices have been rising faster than the rate of i
past decade,
9
many purchased tickets are later resold at significantly higher
secondary market. Some suggest that the persistence of the secondary m
of underpricing by bands in the primary market (and there are variou
10
distribution mechanism that can cater to fans who are less able to purchase on the
primary market. Scholars and industry commentators have offered v
chara
rnative implications for how much social value players in the secondar
create.
12
exclusive agreements, in which the ticket distributor agrees to handle all s
venue for a period
9
Alan B. Krueger, The Economics of Real Superstars: The Market for
in the Material World, 23 J.L. & ECON. 1, 3 (2005).
10
See, e.g., id. at 13.
11
Pascal Courty, Some Economics of Ticket Resale, 17 J. ECON.PERSP.
(suggesting that ticket resale is a function of heterogeneous consum
some consumers prefer to plan ahea
Rock Concerts
85, 86 (2003)
er preferences, in that
d while others prefer delay scheduling decisions,
even if it requires paying higher prices).
12
Although an assessment of the secondary market is beyond the scope of this paper,
some commentators on the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger have expressed concern for
how the merger would affect the secondary market. Any such assessment would first
have to articulate what services the secondary market provides, whether those services
enhance social welfare, and whether direct competition between the primary and
secondary markets enhances social welfare.
7
negotiated between the ticket distributor and the venue. Most such agreements run for
ts expire in any given
ticket
dist e contract.
15
r venues,
establish whatever putative “processing fees” (alternatively called handling, convenience,
ing fee revenues
16
re fixed by a
ny cases, the
ue with an
improvements
to the venue or even construction of the venue itself. The upfront payment amounts to a
discount to the effective price the venue pays for distribution.
17
The allocation of these
fees, along with the length of the contract and any other payments or discounts,
determines the effective price charged by the ticket distributor for the services it provides
has become
13
several years, with typical contracts lasting at least three and running for an average of
six, and approximately 20 percent of all ticket distribution contrac
year,
14
and as these contracts approach their expiration dates, competing
ributors place bids with venues to compete for a subsequent exclusiv
These distribution agreements appoint ticket distributors as agents fo
or service fees) that are charged to ticket purchasers, and allocate process
between the distributor and the venue. Such processing fees usually a
schedule agreed to by the parties and can vary from event to event. In ma
ticket distribution agreement will require the distributor to provide the ven
upfront payment, which might help the venue to finance certain physical
to venues. There is evidence that the ticket distribution services industry
13
See Ticketmaster Corp. v. Tickets.com, Inc., 2003-1 Trade Cas. (CCH)
96,239-40 (C.D. Cal. 2003) (describing process of “
¶74,013, at
arms length” bargaining between
sulting price structure).
14
See id. at 96,240-41 (reporting that at least 20 percent of such contracts expire each
year).
15
Id. (describing this bidding process).
16
This should dispel the misconception, implicit in some critiques of the transaction,
that the ticket distributor is solely responsible for, and retains all of, the processing fees.
Typically, none of the processing fee revenues go to the artists.
17
See Ticketmaster Corp, 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,240.
venues and ticket distribution companies and re
8
increasingly competitive in recent years, resulting in a larger percentage of the processing
fees (or larger upfront paym
18
et sales, in
venues have
y operating their own
others or
developed themselves or, more frequently, by licensing software from technology
ple, by selling
er venues may
ands of
particularly
demanding for events where demand exceeds supply, such as playoff sporting events and
marquee concerts). Several technology companies, such as Paciolan (acquired by
, TicketReturn, and
AudienceView, have developed and made available for licensing ticket distribution
n behalf in lieu
offer
ents) allocated to venues and promoters.
There are other mechanisms available to venues to administer tick
addition to outsourcing this task to a distributor. An increasing number of
chosen to “make” instead of “buy” their ticket distribution, either b
ticket distribution services with technology they have purchased from
companies. Many venues have pursued a hybrid strategy, outsourcing their ticket
distribution services while engaging in some self-distribution, for exam
directly to season ticket holders or purchasers at the box office. Larg
demand more sophisticated software than smaller venues, to handle the dem
responding to a high volume of simultaneous ticket purchases (this is
Ticketmaster in 2008), Veritix, Front Gate, ShoWare, Tessitura
technologies that enable individual venues to distribute tickets on their ow
of outsourcing this task to agents such as Ticketmaster.
19
These firms
18
The Potential Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed Combin
Entertainment Inc. and Live Nation, Inc., Hearing on Competition in t
ation of Ticketmaster
he Ticketing and
Promotion Industry Before the Subcomm. on Courts and Competition Policy of the
House Comm. on the Judiciary, 111 Cong. (2009) [hereinafter Froeb Testimony]
(written testimony of Luke Froeb, Oehmig Associate Professor of Management at
Vanderbilt University).
19
See infra notes 89-102 and accompanying text (listing numerous examples of venues
that have recently taken on the task of distributing their own tickets). See also
Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241 (explaining that the option of self-
9
technologically sophisticated support for venues’ efforts to gather, synthesize, and
info ng strategies.
20
istribution
rts Enterprises based
n, Comcast-
Spectacor (“Comcast”), and many others currently employ internal mechanisms to
21
ftware
t it owns and
verse range of
iary of Major
team is permitted
to develop (and many have) their own ticket distribution capabilities. Other venues
pursue hybrid strategies for separate clienteles, such as season ticket holders versus
rts programs
, and the
interpret information about their ticket buyers, fans, and in some cases, donors,
rmation that can facilitate targeted promotion and more rational prici
A growing number of venues have recently internalized their ticket d
operations relying on these technologies. For example, Kroenke Spo
in Denver, numerous universities, International Speedway Corporatio
distribute tickets over the Internet. Live Nation itself recently received a so
license from CTS to power the self-distribution of tickets to venues tha
manages. Moreover, ticket distribution is being implemented through a di
vertical arrangements. Tickets.com, for example, is owned by a subsid
League Baseball and distributes tickets to MLB games, yet each MLB
single-ticket purchasers. For example, many universities with large spo
(including Maryland, Georgia Tech, West Virginia, North Carolina State
ster from
y applying dynamic,
fetime value of
rs and fans. With the use of advanced Veritix applications, clients have
the unique capability of understanding the nature of the true attendees at every event . . . .
Never before has a single ticketing and live entertainment company delivered such
advanced digital ticketing services and tools that empower clients to truly understand
their customers’ habits, improve fan relationships and drive more revenue.”).
21
See, e.g., infra notes 79-88, 103-110. Note also that the University of Michigan, the
University of Tennessee, and various other universities both self-distribute as well, using
Paciolan technology.
distribution via reliance on outside technology providers prevents Ticketma
exercising market power).
20
See Veritix, www.veritix.com/ (last visited Sept. 9, 2009) (“B
client-branded technologies—like exclusive digital ticketing delivery tools—Veritix
enables its partners to develop rich behavioral profiles that maximize the li
their ticket buye
10
University of Virginia) use technologies “powered by Paciolan” to distribute tickets to
ns that providers
well as the many
pportunities that can become available through integrated ticket
dist
The emergence of varied vertical integration strategies also illustrates how much
distribution
homable for
or perhaps
e. The
centrality of Internet sales has called into question the requirement of establishing retail
booths or call centers, both of which were necessary channels for ticket distribution not
reduced the costs and complexity for venues that decide to
distribute their own tickets. Internet technologies have leapfrogged the once-prevalent
self-
23
the public but maintain separate systems for student ticketing supported by TicketReturn.
These multi-pronged strategies illustrate the many organizational solutio
of live entertainment are currently pursuing for ticket distribution as
ancillary profit o
ribution systems.
the industry has changed in a relatively short period of time. Just eleven years ago,
appellate courts and the enforcement agencies could describe the ticket
industry without mentioning the Internet.
22
Now, it would be unfat
professional ticket distribution to exclude substantial Internet distribution,
even to have anything but Internet distribution as the primary sales vehicl
long ago, and it has drastically
model of telephone and retail distribution and have enabled many venues to
distribute tickets over the Internet.
22
See Campos v. Ticketmaster, 140 F.3d 1166 (8th Cir. 1998); Brie
the United States and Federal Trade Commission, Campos v. Ticketmaster, No. 98-127
f Amicus Curiae for
(Dec. 1998).
23
See United States v. SunGard Data Sys., 172 F. Supp. 2d 172, 188-89 (D.D.C. 2001)
(noting that recent technological advances had significantly reduced the cost of vertical
integration by customers who might otherwise suffer at the hands of a hypothetical
monopolist. Invoking prior decision for the proposition that “the market definition
should be expanded because the ability of a substitute product to compete ‘will be
enhanced in the future because of further technological and market developments.’”).
11
There are similarly many variations in how promoters administer venues.
y lease them
ith others that
ation also are
booking agents,
where they not only organize and promote live performances but also coordinate and
job of
ances. The
enues and
et distributors. It
also suggests that ticket distributors contract directly with venues, whereas sometimes
they instead contract with promoters. But the chart effectively conveys the several
vertical relationships and multiple inputs that are required to deliver live entertainment
and associated products to consumers.
Promoters may merely rent a site for a particular event, but many promoters have long-
term commitments to certain venues. Promoters may own venues (and ma
occasionally to others) and may have additional exclusive arrangements w
preclude competing promoters from the venue. Promoters such as Live N
providing services that traditionally have remained under the control of
arrange lengthy tours at many venues.
Figure 1, created by Barclay’s Capital, does a reasonably good
characterizing the different contractual relationships that enable live perform
chart understates the variation in both the extent of integration between v
promoters as well as the extent of integration between venues and tick
12
Parties to Proposed Merger
The parties to this proposed merger, Live Nation and Ticketmas
several of the market segments described above. Ticketmaster Enterta
ter, are leaders in
inment, Inc.,
includes Ticketmaster, “the world’s leading live entertainment ticketing and marketing
company,”
24
Front Line Management Group, “the world’s leading artist management
a handful of other business company,”
25
TicketsNow, a secondary ticket seller, and
24
See About Ticketmaster Entertainment, Inc., http://www.ticketmaster.com/h/about_
us.html?tm_link=tm_homeA_i_abouttm (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
25
Id.
13
interests. Ticketmaster’s central asset, and its primary mechanism for distributing
one and at retail
les account for
age that
l locations (not
including those at the locations of the venues themselves) account for just 16 percent of
overall transactions, a proportion that is fa
et sales than any
(which are based on
gh TicketNews
claims that Web traffic “has been shown to be a good estimator of the number of
transactions made by a seller”
27
), Ticketmaster.com is the leading seller both among
recorded sales
-scale popular
26
tickets, is its signature Website, Ticketmaster.com, but it was not always so. Before
Internet commerce became routine, Ticketmaster’s sales over the teleph
outlets dominated the firm’s business. Currently, however, Internet sa
more than 73 percent of the company’s worldwide sales, a growing percent
reflects the rapidly evolving nature of the industry. Sales from 6,700 retai
lling, and its 19 call centers account for 11
percent.
Ticketmaster.com attracts more Web traffic and enjoys more tick
other Internet sales site. According to TicketNews’ power rankings
Web traffic received by a ticket seller’s Web site, not actual sales, thou
primary and overall ticket sellers, with about 60 percent and 31 percent of
respectively.
28
Some sources indicate that Ticketmaster’s share for large
26
s.
htm
27
us y_ra (last visited
Sep
28
the fo ng power
sco y and combined ticket se
Top Primary Sellers Score Top Combined Sellers Score
1 Ticketmaster.com 60.29 1 Ticketmaster.com 30.68
2 LiveNation.com 16.11 2 StubHub.com 20.14
3 Telecharge.com 4.89 3 LiveNation.com 8.17
4 TicketWeb.com 3.50 4 TicketsNow.com 5.48
5 ETix.com 3.16 5 TicketLiquidator.com 3.33
See Ticketmaster Businesses & Interests, http://www.ticketmaster.com/h/businesse
l (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
See TicketNews, http://www.ticketnews.com/ticket_ind tr nkings
t. 9, 2009).
For the week ending August 22, 2009, TicketNews reports llowi
res for primar llers:
14
music events might be even higher, approaching 75-90 percent. Other full service
n outsourced
other, a distinction we find to
be o
es a significant
position in the market for talent management and “is widely regarded as the music
world's m ent com
31
29
ticket distributors appear to have much smaller market shares, with most below 5 percent.
Unfortunately, public data regarding ticket sales do not distinguish betwee
distribution, on the one hand, and self-distribution, on the
f great competitive significance, as discussed in Part III, below.
30
Ticketmaster Entertainment’s Front Line Management occupi
ost powerful artist-managem pany.” Front Line’s roster includes close
erTicke 1.82 2.48
7 Tix.com 1.80 7 TicketCity.com 2.31
1.77
1.60
ts.com 1.16
e self-distributed tickets, a
ave no
rces we consult
lightly different
at
s from January
thly unique visitors,
audience also
ster’s
/www.nielsen-online.com/emc/btn/0902_
York Times reported
nt of the $21
Stifel Nicolaus suggesting that
ent. Andrew
kin, ed., Ticketmaster Merger Plan Could Touch on Antitrust, N.Y. T
IMES, Feb.
4, 2009, at B3.
29
Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241.
30
We anticipate that the ultimate fact finder will have superior data that both
distinguishes between outsourced and self-distribution and is not derived from proxy
information, such as TicketNews’s power rankings.
31
Ethan Smith, Ticketmaster to Acquire Star Power in Azoff Deal, WALL ST. J., Oct. 23,
2008, at B1.
6 BrownPap ts.com 6 Telecharge.com
8 Tickets.com 1.20 8 TicketWeb.com
9 Wantickets.com 0.96 9 ETix.com
10 SmithsTix.com 0.44 10 CoasttoCoastTicke
Id. (last visited Aug. 31, 2009) These figures apparently includ
fact that explains LiveNation.com’s inclusion on the list.
Data sources for ticket sales conflict slightly with each other, and we h
knowledge suggesting that one source is superior to others, but all the sou
generate similar results. For example, Nielsen Online Netview offers a s
comparison of Ticketmaster and LiveNation.com that perhaps indicates th
LiveNation.com has a less significant Web presence. Indeed, its figure
2009 reveal that Ticketmaster attracts roughly 12.1 million mon
almost four times LiveNation.com’s, and 53 percent of LiveNation.com’s
visited Ticketmaster in January 2009, whereas only 14 percent of Ticketma
audience visited LiveNation.com. See http:/
indnews/indnews_0902.htm (last visited Sept. 9, 2009). The New
data from Forrester Research indicating that Ticketmaster had 30 perce
billion events market in 2008 and data from
Ticketmaster’s market share for music concert tickets was closer to 70 perc
Ross Sor
15
to 200 artists, including many who perform in large venues. Ticketmaster’s purchase of
as an effort “to
ifts.”
32
The merger of
f
odel, in which it is integrating its ticketing operations with
oth
Live Nation, Inc. describes itself as “the largest producer of live concerts in the
33
Live
tes many others in
for 159
of the
o 38 percent
of all live music concerts, although Live Nation owns or operates approximately 90
percent of the outdoor amphitheatres in the US. At congressional hearings, many smaller
es have complained that they cannot offer marquee bands the revenues and venues
them to compete with Live Nation.
Front Line in October 2008 was characterized by The Wall Street Journal
find a new business model for an industry undergoing seismic sh
Ticketmaster Entertainment with Live Nation appears to be a continuation o
Ticketmaster’s new business m
er elements of live entertainment.
world, annually producing over 16,000 concerts for 1,500 artists in 57 countries.”
Nation owns 18 venues in the US, has leases on 70 more, and opera
which it organizes live events.
34
With its subsidiaries, it has booking rights
venues, with 140 in the US, and has been responsible for organizing many
industry’s largest tours.
35
Live Nation events represent approximately 35 t
venu
that would enable
36
32
Id.
33
See About Live Nation, http://www.livenation.com/company/getCompanyInfo (last
on of Ticketmaster
ation, Inc., Hearing on Competition in the Ticketing and
try Before the Subcomm. on Courts and Competition Policy of the
House Comm. on the Judiciary, 111 Cong. 13 (2009) [hereinafter Rapino Testimony]
(written testimony of Michael Rapino, President & Chief Executive Officer, Live
Nation).
35
Live Nation, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10-K) at 1 (Mar. 5, 2009) http://www.sec.
gov/Archives/edgar/data/1335258/000119312509045320/0001193125-09-045320-
index.htm (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
36
See supra, note 2.
visited Sept. 9, 2009).
34
The Potential Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed Combinati
Entertainment Inc. and Live N
Promotion Indus
16
Live Nation, like Ticketmaster Entertainment, also has been expanding into
plement a new
n MusicToday, an
e company’s
ge their
eir fan bases and provide a direct connection” in marketing music,
tickets, and merchandise.
ow internally
icketmaster
ive Nation ended
an agreement
with CTS Eventim, the largest ticketing company in Europe, to license CTS ticket
distribution technology. The agreement enabled Live Nation to create a technological
it owns or
t sales
mber 2008 that
it had entered a strategic alliance with venue-operator SMG, currently a Ticketmaster
client. According to public reports, the agreement contemplates that Live Nation will sell
otes
vertically related segments of live entertainment in an apparent effort to im
business model. In 2006, Live Nation acquired a controlling interest i
online store for artist merchandise, and MusicToday became part of th
“Artist Nation” division, which “was formed to partner with artists to mana
diverse rights, grow th
37
In another recent effort to integrate downstream into consumer sales, and thus to
gain greater contact with consumer sales and preferences, Live Nation n
maintains its own ticket distribution operations. Previously a long-time T
client (and the source of 17% of Ticketmaster’s revenues in 2007), L
most of its dealings with Ticketmaster in December 2008 after it entered
platform so the company could distribute tickets to events at the venues
operates, and the resulting (captive) sales account for all or most of the ticke
currently attributed to Live Nation. Live Nation also announced in Septe
tickets to events at venues operated by SMG, regardless whether Live Nation prom
37
Press Release, PRNewswire, Live Nation's Artist Nation Division Redefines the
Music Industry with Unified Rights Model, (Oct. 16, 2007),
http://www.prnewswire.co.uk /cgi/news/release?id=210077 (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
17
such events, after SMG’s contract with Ticketmaster expires in December, 2010.
38
master.
39
Some
tmaster is
other distributors for Ticketmaster’s business as
n contracts expire.
Recent Industry Developments
a live
dustry that is undergoing significant structural change.
40
Accordingly,
the company’s proposed merger should be viewed within the context of a rapidly shifting
industry landscape.
Currently, LiveNation.com, which distributes tickets to events at Live Nation venues, is
ranked a distant second in Internet primary ticket sales, behind Ticket
industry observers expect Live Nation (if and until its merger with Ticke
consummated) to compete along with
Ticketmaster’s distributio
Both Ticketmaster Entertainment’s and Live Nation’s recent acquisitions, and
their respective pursuits of new business models, appear to be responses to
entertainment in
38
See Live Nation Signs Ticketing deal with SMG, Reuters News Servi
11, 2008);
ce (September
334097
ecember 31,
t fraction of
ousand tickets
09.”). This is
p to 5 million
te all SMG
ends that most
y SMG are in fact owned by municipalities that employ a “request for
utors and that
tmaster expects to compete for such business even after its current contract with
SMG expires on December 31, 2010. Id. See also Michael Peters, Ticketmaster
Responds to Live Nation/SMG Deal, B
ILLBOARD MAG., Sept. 11, 2008, available at:
http://www.billboard.biz/bbbiz/content_display/industry/e3ia6592177cf3e47ef913e13148
951ec2e (recounting Ticketmaster’s characterization of the deal and SMG’s response).
39
See supra, note 28.
40
See supra, note 31 (describing the music world as “an industry undergoing seismic
shifts”).
http://investors.ticketmaster.com/releasedetail.cfm?releaseid=
(detailing Ticketmaster’s exclusive agreements with SMG that expire on D
2010). Ticketmaster has argued that Live Nation would sell only a modes
tickets to SMG-operated venues by late 2009. See id. (“[L]ess than 250 th
(of the 141 million we sold in 2007) are at possible risk with SMG in 20
because, in part, although events at SMG-operated venues account for u
tickets annually, Ticketmaster suggests that the arrangement will not obliga
venues to rely upon Live Nation for ticket distribution. Ticketmaster cont
venues operated b
proposal” or “competitive bidding” process for selecting their ticket distrib
Ticke
18
Perhaps the most significant development in the music industry, one with effects
t the emergence
oth significantly
es in ticket
l evidence for a
“Bowie hypothesis” that suggests that “concert prices have soared because recording
lementary
42
nderpriced their
closer to what
is hypothesis,
rt revenues,
fewer tickets sold, larger yet fewer concerts, and fewer sellouts. Krueger additionally
finds evidence for a predicted “superstar” effect that has channeled a disproportionately
larg hese popular
ination, with the
seat.
In other words, data on concert ticket prices suggest that since 1997 concerts are
er than being
become the
well beyond live entertainment, is the Internet-driven spread of digital music technology
and the concomitant rise of music piracy. Alan Krueger has observed tha
of digital music coincided with a rise in concert ticket prices that was b
faster than the rate of inflation and additionally faster than similar increas
prices to movies, theatre, and sporting events.
41
Krueger finds empirica
artists have seen a large decline in their income from record sales, a comp
product to concerts.” In other words, whereas performers previously u
concert tickets in order to boost their record sales, they now are charging
the market will bear. Consistent with the economic theory underlying th
these ticket price increases have been associated with higher overall conce
e and growing share of concert revenues to the most popular bands. T
and established bands also seem to be engaging in more price discrim
prices for good concert seats rising faster than the price for the average
increasingly being priced like single-market monopoly products, rath
underpriced to boost popularity and record sales. They have accordingly
41
Krueger, supra note 9, at 7-10.
42
Id. at 25. Kruger calls this the “Bowie hypothesis” because of David Bowie’s
prescient remark in 2002 that “music itself is going to becomes like running water or
electricity,” which meant that performers “better be prepared for doing a lot of touring
because that’s really the only unique situation that’s going to be left.” Id. at 26.
19
primary source of revenue for most top artists. In turn, they have unleashed new
bined with the
itable opportunities for promoters who organize
eve
ar pursuit of
t value chain. Live
Nation’s development of MusicToday and Artist Nation reflect these new Internet
ing more
tnessed the
tribution
is spread of
Internet technologies for ticket distribution, along with the growing economic importance
of concerts, has meant that ticket platforms also have become important mediums to
tribution market
has historically taken the form of technological rivalry—Ticketmaster’s displacement of
gical capabilities—
urced distributors or
43
revenue opportunities for concert promoters and, especially when com
“superstar effect,” have opened prof
nts for the nation’s marquee performers.
Additionally, emerging Internet technologies are permitting a simil
new revenue opportunities in other segments of the live entertainmen
opportunities to sell merchandise and other goods. Meanwhile, Internet technologies—
including technologies to distribute tickets over the Internet—are becom
widespread and commoditized. As noted above, recent years have wi
emergence of several technology companies that license or sell ticketing dis
technologies to venues that choose to distribute their own tickets.
44
Th
market merchandise and related goods. Consequently, the locus of competition in ticket
distribution appears to be shifting. Whereas competition in the ticket dis
Ticketron as the market leader was largely due to its superior technolo
competition now increasingly revolves around the ability of outso
43
Marie Connolly & Alan B. Krueger, Rockonomics: The Economics of Popular
Music, at Table 1.1, NBER Working Paper No. W11282 (Apr. 2005).
44
See infra notes 79-110 and accompanying text (listing numerous examples of venues
that have recently taken on the task of distributing their own tickets). See also
Ticketmaster Corp 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241 (explaining that the option of self-
distribution via reliance on outside technology providers prevents Ticketmaster from
exercising market power).
20
firms that support self-distribution to assist venues in promoting and marketing content
and related products.
oducts explain
y would
common when
scale market
production. If competition were truly over efficient ticket distribution, then the
Internet ticketing technology and reduced costs in ticket distribution has given
rise self-
rs and artists who
are pursuing new revenue sources by establishing greater contact with fans. For example,
revenue sources that traditionally accompany live entertainment, such as merchandise
s if they maintain
hese profit
g and interpreting
ues and
performers to develop targeted communications and marketing strategies designed to
tainment.
These opportunities are lost if independent ticket distribution firms lack the incentive to
The growing importance of marketable content and ancillary pr
what would otherwise appear to be an economic curiosity. Economic theor
normally predict that the outsourcing of a particular service becomes more
its underlying technology becomes commoditized and thus subject to large-
45
industry would rely on outsourced services. In contrast to this prediction, however, the
spread of
to greater vertical integration, as venues are now increasingly pursuing
distribution strategies.
This trend in vertical integration is apparently driven by promote
sales and perhaps music sales, might accrue to venues and performer
contact with consumers. The “superstar” effect additionally magnifies t
opportunities, especially for top-name performers. Similarly, acquirin
information about the profile of ticket purchasers facilitates efforts by ven
respond to consumer preferences and maximize fan demand for live enter
45
See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON,MARKETS &HIERARCHIES (1975). Cf. George J.
Stigler, The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of Market, 59 J. POL.ECON. 185
(1951).
21
develop such profiles and acquire a more thorough understanding, and a broader data set,
e
about establishing direct linkages to, and
info
e Nation
at it needs to integrate
away from the increasingly competitive market for ticket distribution,
47
and both
ore
s. This industry-wide shift towards vertical integration, and the
acc ains both parties’
ty of live
concerts and the economic opportunities afforded by vertical integration—not only might
explain Live Nation’s and Ticketmaster’s intentions to merge, but should also inform any
g two sections, we
of performers’ fans. Accordingly, the value of ticket distribution services has becom
less about technological capabilities and more
rmation about, fans and their interests in content.
46
Such trends comport with public statements by Ticketmaster and Liv
explaining their rationale for the merger. Ticketmaster has noted th
companies have argued that their integration would enable the production of m
content and more product
ompanying opportunities to pursue additional revenue sources, expl
motivations for the transaction.
These industry-wide developments—the growing economic centrali
evaluation of how the merger might affect competition. In the followin
46
Veritix.com, http://www.veritix.com (last visited Sept. 9, 2009) (descri
Veritix self-ticketing technology allows venues to “develop rich behavioral
maximize the lifetime value of their ticket buyers and their fans” an
truly understand their customers’ habits, improve fan relationships, and
revenue”).
47
See
bing how
profiles that
d “empower clients to
drive more
Peter Kafka, Ticketmaster CEO Irving Azoff: How to Make Money While Music
Becomes “Demonetized, A
LL THINGS DIGITAL, May 27, 2009, http://d7.allthingsd.com/
20090527/irving-azoff/?mod=ATD_search (last visited Sept. 9, 2009) (reporting that
Ticketmaster’s merger with Live Nation is motivated by Ticketmaster’s need to integrate
with promotion and marketing, without which Ticketmaster’s survival would be
jeopardized, and quoting Azoff as saying “[a]ny of you guys can write a program that
does what Ticketmaster does. . . . I’ve been there a couple of months and I have gripes
myself.”).
22
evaluate the probable consequences of this transaction on horizontal and vertical
competition while keeping these industry developments in mind.
III. Analysis of Merger’s Horizontal Consequences
An analysis of the horizontal consequences of the Live Nation-Tick
merger begins with identifying the market segments in which both c
although both firms have core businesses that lie primarily in specific segm
now participates in multiple levels of the industry. Live Nation currently en
promotion of concerts and other events, the operation and management o
forms of merchandising, and the distribution of primary tickets. Ticketm
engages in the distribution of primary ticke
etmaster
ompanies compete.
The production of live entertainment involves a number of market segments, and
ents, each
gages in the
f venues, various
aster meanwhile
ts, the secondary market for ticket sales, the
licensing of technology that facilitates the self-distribution of tickets for a venue’s own
events, and the management of entertainment talent.
into direct
e Nation, which
nts
distribution
services to other venues. Accordingly, the parties now appear to be competing for
contracts to provide ticket distribution services to venues that choose not to distribute
their own tickets. This recent competition has led some to criticize the transaction on the
ground that it purportedly reduces present and future competition in a market for ticket
Consequently, most of both firms’ business activities do not come
competition with each other. However, on January 1 of this year, Liv
was previously an important Ticketmaster client, began to self-distribute tickets to eve
at venues it owns or operates and has also sought to offer outsourced ticket
23
distribution services, and it impels us to examine the horizontal consequences of this
transaction.
are numbers
of the industry
sales that this
uggests that
technological innovations have made this a very dynamic and rapidly changing market, in
e
ion for events it
nt or future
defined market for ticket distribution.
Con t would have a
minimal effect on the market’s competitiveness.
The remainder of this section employs the law of horizontal mergers as the
osed
ent agencies to
ascertain the competitive impact of a transaction upon “any line of commerce or [line of]
alysis generally
market
By most publicly available accounts, Ticketmaster and Live Nation
one and two in ticket sales,
48
with combined sales approaching 80 percent
total.
49
Some critics decry the purported reduction of competition in such
merger would entail. A careful analysis of this market segment, however, s
which new products are facilitating vertical integration and easing entry. At the sam
time, Live Nation’s ticket sales, nearly all of which entail distribut
promotes or venues it owns or operates, significantly overstate its prese
competitive significance in any properly
sequently, an appropriate evaluation of the merger suggests that i
framework for evaluating the probable horizontal consequences of the prop
transaction. Section 7 of the Clayton Act requires courts and enforcem
activity affecting commerce in any section of the country.”
50
Such an an
involves the following steps: 1) defining the relevant market, 2) identifying
48
Live Nation is primarily considered a large ticket distributor on account of its self-
distribution of its own tickets. This qualification becomes meaningful in a horizontal
merger analysis, see infra notes 129-130 and accompanying text.
49
See, e.g., supra note 27 (attributing 60.3% and 16.1% of the market for ticket sales to
Ticketmaster, and Live Nation, respectively). Of course, TicketNews scores are only
approximations of relative sales.
50
15 U.S.C. §18 (2006).
24
participants and calculating market shares, 3) analyzing “other factors” that bear upon
ining possibilities for
itive effects, and 5)
hether the merger might create horizontal efficiencies.
51
Ma
f the country,”
courts and the enforcement agencies must determine the relevant product market(s) and
52
enforcement agencies, bear the burden of pleading and
pro . Failure to discharge these burdens
doo
The market definition inquiry does not involve identifying “markets” in a
colloquial sense or even in the sense that market participants or industry observers may
igorous process
nse that firms
whether a transaction will produce anticompetitive effects; 4) exam
entry in the market, assuming the possibility of anticompet
determining w
rket Definition
To ascertain the relevant “line[s] of commerce” and “section[s] o
geographic market(s) in which the merging parties participate. Plaintiffs challenging a
merger, including the federal
ving the relevant product and geographic markets
ms any challenge to a merger.
53
1. General Standards Governing Market Definition
employ the term.
54
Instead, market definition in the merger context is a r
designed to identify markets that are “economically meaningful” in the se
51
See 1992 Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizo
Guidelines, § 0.2 [hereinafter 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines].
52
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962).
ntal Merger
7) (government
United States v.
of market definition a
predicate” for a successful challenge to a merger); id. at 1152-68 (rejecting
challenge because of failure to establish a relevant market); SunGard, 172 F. Supp. 2d at
181-93 (rejecting government challenge to a merger because of failure to prove relevant
market in which transaction would result in significant concentration).
54
2006 Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Commentary on the
Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 11-12 (Mar. 2006) [hereinafter 2006 Commentary on
Horizontal Merger Guidelines] (“Industry Usage of the Word ‘Market’ is Not
Controlling”).
53
See United States v. Engelhard Corp., 126 F.3d 1302 (11th Cir. 199
challenge to merger fails for lack of proof of relevant product market);
Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098, 1110 (N.D. Ca. 2004) (proof
“necessary
25
participating in them could exercise market power. If the participants in a proposed
market, then
ingful and cannot serve as the basis for
an e
ious factors
(“practical indicia”) purportedly bearing upon the “reasonable interchangeability” of
57
ore
f courts.
58
cluding but
not necessarily lim with respect to
market power
55
market could not exercise market power, even when acting in concert, because a
sufficient number of consumers would turn to products outside the putative
the “market” in question is not economically mean
valuation of the competitive effects of the transaction.
56
At one time, market definition involved the consideration of var
potential substitutes. More recently, the enforcement agencies have articulated a m
rigorous analytic process that has been embraced by an increasing number o
Under this approach, the agencies seek to identify a category of products, in
ited to the type of products sold by the merging parties,
which a hypothetical monopolist of such products could profitably exercise
Joint Merger Guidelines, supra note 51, § 1.0 (“The analytic process
on] ensures
text of
e exercise of
bearing upon
ent of Justice
also Oracle
ct market is
Joint Merger
pp. 2d at 181-82
, since the
necessarily impact any analysis of the anticompetitive effects of
the transaction"; invoking both “reasonable interchangeability” test and agencies’
hypothetical monopolist test); FTC v. Swedish Match N. Am., Inc., 131 F. Supp. 2d 151,
159-60 (D.D.C. 2000) (“practical indicia” are “not necessarily criteria to be rigidly
applied” in a “talismanic fashion”; explaining that 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines’
hypothetical monopolist test is one method for evaluating “price sensitivity” and thus
reasonable interchangeability) (quotations omitted); FTC v. Cardinal Health, 12 F. Supp.
2d 34, 45, n.8 (D.D.C. 1998).
55
See 1992
described in this section [describing the standards governing market definiti
that the Agency evaluates the likely competitive impact of a merger within the con
economically meaningful markets, i.e., markets that could be subject to th
market power.”).
56
See id., § 1.0.
57
See Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325 (identifying various “practical indicia”
reasonable interchangeability and thus market definition).
58
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, supra note 51, § 1.0; 1984 Departm
Merger Guidelines, §§ 2.1, 2.11 [hereinafter 1984 Merger Guidelines]. See
Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d at 1110-13 (explaining that proof of relevant produ
“necessary predicate” for successful merger challenge and invoking
Guidelines’ hypothetical monopolist methodology); SunGard, 172 F. Su
(market definition is the “key to the ultimate resolution of this type of case
scope of the market will
26
because an insufficient numbers of purchasers would avail themselves of substitutes for
the category of products in question.
59
ncy to identify
rovisional market.
d sometimes
promoters) to provide ticketing services for a particular event or series of events.
ase their tickets from these distributors,
who chasers of the ticket
by a
sumer, is often
central to a proper application of the antitrust laws. Numerous decisions in the merger
context have properly determined that business firms, and not individual downstream
hypothetical
oduct to ultimate
consumers.
60
Moreover, the Eighth Circuit Court of Appeals, on precisely this question
in a previous suit involving Ticketmaster, ruled that venues, and not fans, are the initial
viders of
2. Identification of Relevant Consumers
Applying the hypothetical monopolist test requires the court or age
the class of purchasers of the product or products that comprise the p
As is detailed in Part II, ticket distributors are retained by venues (an
Accordingly, even though concert goers purch
act as agents for venues, it is the venues who are the true pur
distribution services.
Understanding this arrangement, in which a distributor is retained
manufacturer or service provider and acts as a liaison to the ultimate con
purchasers, are the relevant consumers for the purpose of conducting the
monopolist test, even if these businesses themselves sell a resulting pr
and direct purchasers of services provided by Ticketmaster and similar pro
59
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, supra note 51, §§ 1.0, 1.11.
60
See, e.g., Cardinal Health, Inc., 12 F. Supp. 2d at 36 (defining market of wholesale
warehousing and distribution of pharmaceuticals sold to retail pharmacies); Grumman
Corp. v. LTV Corp., 665 F.2d 10, 13-14 (2d Cir. 1981) (approving product market of
“major airframe subassemblies” sold to manufacturers of civilian aircraft).
27
ticketing distribution services. Additionally, the Department of Justice and the Federal
l purchasers of
is an
er, the venues
he typical contract
provides that the venue is the ‘Principal’ who grants to Ticketmaster a right ‘to sell
Principal’s agent
63
ines, the
whether a price increase by all ticket distributors
wou heir purchases of ticket distribution services so as
to r
3. Geographic and Product Markets
Given the portability of Internet software and the ease with which ticket
distributors can provide services throughout the country, there are unlikely to be any
geographic boundaries to this market. In a related determination in 2003, before Internet
ketmaster
61
Trade Commission jointly filed a Supreme Court brief in 1999 endorsing an Eighth
Circuit determination that venues, and not consumers, are the actua
Ticketmaster’s ticket distribution services.
62
The joint DOJ and FTC brief
instructive interpretation of the economic relationship between Ticketmast
it serves, and fans of live entertainment. As the brief pointed out, “[t]
[tickets] as the .’” Thus, we think it likely that, for purposes of
applying the hypothetical monopolist test articulated by the Merger Guidel
Department of Justice will examine
ld cause enough venues to reduce t
ender such a price increase unprofitable.
software became as widespread as it is now, a federal court found that Tic
61
See Campos, 140 F.3d at 1171-72 .
62
See Brief Amicus Curiae for the United States and the Federal Trade Co
Campos v. Ticketmaster, N
mmission in
o. 98-127 (Dec. 1998).
63
See id. at 9 (quoting plaintiff’s complaint) (emphasis in the brief). Like the Eighth
Circuit’s opinion, the joint brief of the DOJ and the FTC treated the allegations in the
plaintiff’s complaint about the nature of the relationship between venues and ticket
distribution companies as true, given the procedural posture of the case, i.e., appellate
review of a decision to grant a motion to dismiss. We have no reason to believe that
these particular allegations were not well-grounded in facts about the industry at the time
or that these facts have changed.
28
competed in markets throughout the United States, and a court is likely to similarly
define the market now.
sers of ticket
acities of 20,000,
smaller
hrough any
combination of four different channels: the Internet, telephone call centers, sales from the
66
oters’ needs for
erent
tain ticket
ets
from their own box office and making group sales and/or selling season tickets.
Moreover, some venues and promoters rely upon distributors to support their box office,
to handle large
volumes of ticket orders in a short period of time, e.g., shortly after the announcement of
ssist in
utors to assist
64
Determining the product market is a more difficult task. Purcha
distribution services range from large stadiums and arenas, with cap
50,000 or even 100,000 fans, to amphitheaters and local clubs with much
capacities.
65
In addition, ticket distributors can supply distribution efforts t
venue’s box office, and retail distribution outlets, the latter of which are generally located
in shopping malls or large department stores. Venues’ and prom
distribution services can vary significantly, and they also can purchase diff
assortments of services. For example, it is common for venues to re
distributors while also engaging in some self-distribution by, for instance, selling tick
season ticket, and group sales operations, while others require distributors
a popular concert or playoff schedule, and others expect distributors to a
promoting the venue’s events. Finally, venues increasingly expect distrib
64
See Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241 (determining that
compete i
the parties
n markets throughout the nation).
65
For example, Ticketmaster’s current clients include both Madison Square Garden,
“the world’s most famous arena,” http://www.thegarden.com/, and Mercury Lounge, a
Bowery Ballroom venue in New York City with a capacity of only 575. See Ben Sisario,
A Small Strategy for Selling Concerts, N.Y. TIMES, June 7, 2001, available at
http://www.nytimes.com/2007/06/07/arts/music/07bowe.html?pagewanted=all
66
See Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,239-40 (describing these channels of
distribution).
29
the venue in managing customer-related information, so as to better gauge fans’
eaningfully
67
vidually negotiated
sion of ticket
ue and presumably the particularized service expectations for each particular
ven
A prior court defined the product market (though only for the sake of argument)
69
thus separating distribution services for large venues from those designed for small ones.
ment needs of
preferences for live entertainment and ancillary products. Such services m
facilitate the venue’s subsequent targeted promotional efforts. Indi
contracts between ticket distributors and venues memorialize the divi
reven
ue.
68
as “the market for full service ticket distribution services purchased by major venues,”
Observers supporting this distinction claim that the technological and equip
67
Indeed, we understand that in many cases loyal fans of particular enter
learn that th
tainers never
motional efforts. See
ry,
Q
ns given by fans
auged
se fans who it
e infra Part
ptation and
ntracts with
d distributor).
t relevant
FTC v. PPG
gainst merger
craft
d as “major
eing and McDonnell Douglas).
In a different context, an economist has drawn a distinction between firms able to serve
large and small clients, on the one hand, and those only able to serve smaller clients, on
the other. See Mary W. Sullivan, The Effect of the Big Eight Accounting Mergers on the
Market for Audit Services, 45 J.L. & E
CON. 375, 396 (2002) (building model based upon
distinction between “Big Eight” accounting firms, on the one hand, and so-called “fringe”
firms, on the other); id. at 386 (“Fringe firms are reasonable alternatives to the Big Eight
for small audit buyers, and the fringe firms are fairly competitive.”).
eir favorite performer is “in town,” despite vigorous pro
Michael Rapino, Transcript of Hearing of Senate Committee on the Judicia
Subcommittee on Antitrust, Competition Policy, and Consumer Rights, C
Transcriptions, LLC (Feb. 24, 2009) (testifying that one of the top reaso
for not attending a concert is that they were unaware of the performance).
Note in this connection that a venue can reduce its expenses on broad-g
advertising and prom d thootion if it can instead target its advertising towar
believes will have a particular interest in attending the event in question. Se
IV.3 (discussing efficiencies—specifically, the benefits of coordinated ada
targeted promotion—that often accompany vertical integration).
68
Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,240 (explaining that co
venues are individually negotiated and allocate revenues between venue an
69
See id. at 96,239-40 (describing and adopting for the sake of argumen
product market including only ticket distribution for large venues). See also
Indus., 798 F.2d 1500 (D.C. Cir. 1986) (affirming preliminary injunction a
between firms that produced glass and acrylic transparencies for sales to air
manufacturers); Grumman Corp., 665 F.2d at 13 (approving market define
airframe assemblies for large civilian aircraftsold to Bo
30
large venues are qualitatively distinct from those of smaller venues, so firms perfectly
70
uch a
size of venues
t otherwise similar
tively
straightforward Internet-based ticket distribution, without complex ancillary services,
ch as gate
ities and other
sis of information
large and small,
serve numerous purposes and promoters organize a diversity of offerings. Popular
venues may host concerts, sporting events, auto shows, and horse shows within a short
period of time. As such, the venue might require a complex bundle of ticket distribution
services for some events, and a much more modest bundle for others. And, in fact, some
capable of serving the needs of small venues may not be able to serve those of larger
ones. At the same time, no precedent or economic principle compels s
distinction. Moreover, any effort to define a relevant market around the
may fail to capture and account for the great diversity of needs tha
venues might possess. For instance, some large venues may require rela
while other large or even medium-sized venues may require (or believe they require)
ticket distribution in several channels, along with multifaceted services su
control, management of season ticket sales, donor management (for univers
non-profit organizations), event promotion, and collection and synthe
about fans. Adding to this complexity is the fact that many venues, both
70
As one neutral analyst has put it,
Large events are typically associated with ticket sales through multiple
distribution channels, including the Internet, call centers, retail outlets, and the
box office. Considering the potential for a high level of demand for tickets in a
short period of time for large events, ticket distribution service providers must be
able to handle large volumes and coordinate the distribution of tickets through all
channels using complicated software and centralized inventory systems.
See Evren Ergin, Barclays Capital, Ticketmaster-Live Nation Antitrust Analysis, Apr.
30, 2009, at 5.
31
venues employ different ticket distribution companies to service different event or fan
catego
71
with any
tion firms but not
other,
ous facets of the
distribution task themselves. Thus, a legal challenge to this transaction could fail for
rs.
73
We may,
bution services
to large venues and promoters, or at least large venues and promoters with sophisticated
needs, offer a distinctive set of services that constitute an identifiable product market.
74
ries. Promoters also have varying needs for a similarly diverse set of events.
We therefore believe it would be difficult to articulate and prove
precision the existence of a market that includes some ticket distribu
others. There is no clear boundary separating one category of firm from an
particularly in light of the ability of venues and promoters to take on vari
72
this reason alone, i.e., the inability to conceive of, articulate, and prove a tractable
distinction between some providers of ticket distribution services and othe
however, assume for the sake of argument that firms providing ticket distri
71
For example, the American Airlines Center in Dallas, TX uses Tick
concert and NBA Mavericks tickets, but Tickets.com to distribute N
etmaster to sell
HL Stars tickets. See
ter.com/events-and-tickets/purchase_tickets.php (last
lub/page.htm?
etmaster.com/artist/
self-
ower
provide
hile other universities may obtain such
73
See Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d at 1159 (finding that government did not carry its
burden of proving market definition because government’s efforts to “delineate” the
boundaries of the product market could “[not] be expressed in terms to make a judgment
of the court have meaning” and noting that plaintiff’s expert witness had conceded that
there was no “quantitative metric” distinguishing products within the market from those
outside it); SunGard, 172 F. Supp. 2d at 181-83.
74
See Ticketmaster Corp. 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,239-40.
http://www.americanairlinescen
visited Sept. 9, 2009) and NHL.COM Network, http://stars.nhl.com/c
id=39263 (last visited Sept. 9, 2009) ; Ticketmaster, http://www.tick
805932?brand=mavericks (last visited Sept. 9, 2009). Moreover, as noted in Part II,
several universities employ Paciolan software to power most of their ticket
distribution while at the same time relying upon TicketReturn software to p
distribution of tickets to their students.
72
For instance, some universities might require their ticket distributor to
integrated donor management software, w
software from independent vendors.
32
4. Applying the SSNIP Test
n services are
sake of market
“large
se” (SSNIP) in
se would be
profitable in light of that reaction. Key to answering this question is the recognition that
of
reliance on
e licensed
have developed
ies that have enabled
many venues to engage in Internet-based self distribution. These developments reflect
the rapid spread of Internet-based technologies that can handle rigorous ticketing
, reduce the minimum viable scale of ticket distribution, and facilitate the
real bution. Courts
cise of market
75
eir own tickets,
rom third parties, has
Assuming the demands of large purchasers of ticket distributio
distinct from their smaller counterparts, the operative inquiry for the
definition focuses on how such purchasers, what we will provisionally call
venues,” would react to a “small but significant and non-transitory increa
the price of outsourced ticket distribution services, and whether this increa
venues have increasingly turned to self-distributing tickets to their own events in lieu
outsourcing this task to agents such as Ticketmaster. Some have done so in
software they have purchased or developed; more frequently such firms hav
such software from third parties. Indeed, in recent years numerous firms
and offered for licensing Internet-based ticket distribution technolog
demands
ization of the sort of efficiencies not available from outsourced distri
have recognized that such technological dynamism should inform the exer
definition.
Accordingly, the number of large venues that now distribute th
with apparent success, relying upon software they own or license f
75
See SunGard, 172 F. Supp. 2d at 189 (noting that recent technological advances had
significantly reduced the cost of vertical integration by customers who might otherwise
suffer at the hands of a hypothetical monopolist, and invoking prior decision for the
proposition that “the market definition should be expanded because the ability of a
substitute product to compete ‘will be enhanced in the future because of further
technological and market developments.’”).
33
grown significantly. Indeed, one might even say that such self-distribution has become
77
enues do not
ovide numerous
and, in the
highlight some of the firms that provide technological support for such vertical
inte
a software
n Europe, to
anages. As
phasize, Live Nation previously outsourced its
hem. Relying
for events at
2. The Houston-Toyota Center, owned by the Houston Rockets of the National
er of ticket
vents at the
erly a client of
76
an industry trend. Ironically, many of these venues were at one time clients of
Ticketmaster, thereby suggesting that the firm’s exclusive contracts with v
have the exclusionary impact that some have suggested.
78
Below we pr
examples of venues that have taken on the task of distributing their tickets
process,
gration.
1. Live Nation is itself a prime example, having recently received
license from CTS, the leading distributor of entertainment tickets i
power its self-distribution of tickets to venues that it owns and m
opponents of the transaction em
ticket distribution services, relying upon Ticketmaster to provide t
upon this license, Live Nation now distributes millions of tickets
venues that it owns or manages.
Basketball Association, has partnered with Veritix, another develop
distribution software, to facilitate self-distribution of tickets for e
venue, which seats up to 19,000 fans for basketball.
79
Form
76
See Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,239 (noting that g
portion of the [ticket distribution] market where the arena itself does its
“there is a growin
own ticketing
.”).
ous examples of
s. at 96,239
ution).
exclusive
arketplace).
offers professional sports teams, universities
ary ticketing
ting database.
ures a paperless ticketing technology. The company seems capable of handling
large venues as it has had a partnership with the Houston Toyota Center since 2003.”).
See Toyota Houston Center, http://www.houstontoyotacenter.com/ about/atozguide.php
(last visited June 4, 2009) (reporting center’s seating capacity as “18,300 for basketball,
17,800 for hockey [and] up to 19,000 for concerts”);
http://www.nba.com/games/20090514/LALHOU/boxscore.html (last visited June 4,
2009) (reporting attendance of 18,501 in Houston playoff game against the Los Angeles
Lakers).
business using software sold or leased to it by Paciolan . . . or [the plaintiff]
77
See infra notes 79-111110 and accompanying text (discussing vari
recent vertical integration by venues); Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trad. Ca
(discussing “growing portion of the market” characterized by self-distrib
78
See infra notes 169-171 and accompanying text (explaining that such
agreements do not prevent competitive entry into the ticket distribution m
79
See Ergin, supra note 70, at 10 (“Veritix
and entertainment venues an electronic, integrated, primary and second
platform for managing ticket inventory and creat[ing] a relationship marke
It feat
34
Ticketmaster,
80
the Houston-Toyota Center also frequently ho
entertainers, including, in 2009 alone, Beyonce, Brittany Spea
Brothers, Pink, Eric Clapton and Steve Winwood, Elton John & Bil
Nickelback, Celtic Woman, and Fleetwood Mac.
sts premier
rs, the Jonas
ly Joel,
ritix recently entered into a
82
(capacity up to
8,000), and
“Denver’s best
tly announced
e company’s
TicketHorse,
isted above,
Village of
ement thus covers distribution of tickets for the
Denver Nuggets, the Colorado Rapids (professional soccer), Colorado Avalanche
(National Hockey League), the Colorado Crush (Arena Football), and Colorado
Mammoth (National Lacrosse League).
86
81
Ve
similar agreement with Salt Lake City’s EnergySolutions Arena.
3. Kroenke Sports Enterprises owns Denver’s Pepsi Center arena
20,000), Dick’s Sporting Goods Park Stadium (capacity just over 1
Denver’s Paramount Theatre, capacity 1,870, which bills itself as
intimate concert venue.”
83
In July, 2008, Kroenke and Veritix join
a partnership whereby the latter would “provide technology for th
newly established ticketing services organization, TicketHorse.”
84
in turn, provides ticket distribution services for each of the venues l
previously served by Ticketmaster, as well as Infinity Park, in the
Glendale, Colorado.
85
The arrang
80
See Jeff Bounds & Jennifer Dawson, Vertical Alliance in Houston Arena Deal,
/dallas/stories
oyota/Vertical
e of the Internet has opened the door for
”). Vertical
isited Sept. 9,
tor.com/tix/
olutions
om/Veritix-
29188
pt. 9, 2009)
is 18,129 for
ith a center
goodspark.com/Stadium/Facts.aspx (last visited Sept.
-seat home stadium of
rounding 24-field, fully lit soccer complex.”); Paramount
Theater, http://www.paramountdenver.com/ (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
84
See Press Release, Veritix, Kroenke Sports Enterprises to Move Ticketing Operations
for Pepsi Center, Denver Nuggets and Colorado Avalanche to Veritix in 2009 (July 30,
0208), available at http://www.veritix.com/news/Veritix_&_Kroenke_Sports_Extend_
Partnership.pdf (last visited Sept.9, 2009).
85
See TicketHorse, http://www.tickethorse.com/ (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
86
Bounds & Dawson, supra note 81.
D
ALLAS BUS. J., Sept. 19, 2003, available at: http://dallas.bizjournals.com
/2003/09/22/story3.html (last visited Sept.9, 2009) (describing Houston-T
Alliance deal as example of how “the emergenc
smaller rivals, some of whom are quietly stealing Ticketmaster’s business.
Alliance, it should be noted, is the predecessor of Veritix.
81
See supra note 80, http://www.houstontoyotacenter.com/events (last v
2009) (listing June through October 2009 events); http://www.ticketliquida
toyota-center-vv-tickets.aspx (last visited June 19, 2009).
82
See Veritix Signs Exclusive Ticketing Contract for Utah Jazz, EnergyS
Arena, TicketNews (Sept. 9, 2009), available at: http://www.ticketnews.c
signs-exclusive-ticketing-contract-for-Utah-Jazz-EnergySolutions-Arena99
83
See NBA, http//www.nba.com/nuggets/contact/faqs.html (last visited Se
(“The capacity of the Pepsi Center for a Nuggets game is 19,155. Capacity
Avalanche games and 17,600 for concerts with an end stage and 20,100 w
stage.”); http://www.dicksssporting
9, 2009) (“Dicks Sporting Goods Park is comprised of the 18,000
the Colorado Rapids and its sur
35
4. Kroenke recently announced that it is partnering with AEG, a
and manager of venues, to manage the Broomfield event center in B
Colorado.
leading owner
roomfield,
00 for hockey
n the partners and
icketmaster as the
olutions to power
hicago’s Grant
ront Gate also
e Live,
ltipurpose
ment with
laced Ticketmaster as the distributor of tickets to Warehouse Live
91
events at their
AudienceView
to power its self-distribution of tickets to a wide variety of cultural and sporting
, which has a
s Arena,
h enablement
87
The venue is publicly owned and has a capacity of 6,0
and basketball and 7,500 for concerts.
88
If negotiations betwee
the city council are successful, TicketHorse will replace T
distributor of the venue’s tickets.
5. Lollapalooza relies upon software licensed from Front Gate S
its self-distribution of tickets to the event, which takes place at C
Park In 2008, the event drew 225,000 fans over three days.
89
F
recently announced a “long-term ticket selling deal” with Warehous
capacity 1,500, which bills itself as “one of Houston’s signature mu
facilities.”
90
Warehouse Live is affiliated with AEG, and the agree
Front Gate disp
events. According to one neutral source, Front Gate Software powers the
platforms of 1,788 venues that have chosen to distribute tickets for
respective venues.
92
6. The University of Minnesota relies upon software produced by
events, including Big Ten football games at its TCF Bank Stadium
capacity of 50,000, and basketball and hockey games at its William
which has a capacity of 16,000.
93
AudienceView also provides suc
87
See Michael Davidson, Broomfield Event Center to Get N
B
ROOMFIELD ENTERPRISE, Aug. 26, 2009, available at
ew Management, Name,
ldenterprise.
MFIELD ENTERPRISE, Apr. 14,
13140448.
=
b (last visited
lds of Pop, Rock
se Live,
www.warehouselive.com/index.php?content=home&section=1 (last visited [date]).
09) (listing
rammed by AEG.”).
92
See Ergin, supra note 70. It should be noted that Front Gate also maintains a
ticketing agency for venues that outsource their ticket distribution services. See Front
Gate Tickets, http://www.frontgatetickets.com/ (last visited Sept.9, 2009). Front Gate's
clients include the Austin Aztecs, who play at Nelson Field, which has a seating capacity
of 8,800.
93
See Audience View Ticketing, http://www.audienceview.com/customers/?t=6 (last
visited Sept. 9, 2009) (listing customers to include the University of Minnesota);
http://www.broomfie
com/ci_13204115.
88
See By the Numbers: Broomfield Event Center, BROO
2008, available at http://www.broomfieldenterprise.com/ci_
89
See Front Gate Tickets, http://pages.exacttarget.com/page.aspx?QS
c76003443ff9837dd4009700e262f1050f35994654bc7b06880d920a5ce5f38
Sept. 9, 2009); Greg Kot, Turn It Up: A Guided Tour Through the Wor
and Wrap, C . T ., Nov. 6, 2008, available at http://leisureblogs.
HI RIB
chicagotribune.com/turn_it_up/2008/11/parks-aim-to-ex.html.
90
See Front Gate Solutions, http://www.frontgatesolutions.com/index
.php?content=news&item=65 (last visited Sept.9, 2009). See also Warehou
http://
91
See AEG Live, http://aeglive.com/aboutus.php (last visited Sept.9, 20
Warehouse Live as one of the venues “owned, managed and/or prog
36
software to several dozen other clients, including Dartmouth Col
Film Festival, the New York Red Bulls of Major League Soccer,
Liverpool Arena in Liverpool, England.
lege, the Tribeca
and the ACC
lue Jays of
ceView to
95
The Blue Jays play their home games at
racing
143,000
e venues host
R and the
and American Motor
eritix that helped
com.
its “New Era”
by Comcast,
ketball and
by premier
he Wachovia
c Clapton, Keith
Urban, Miley Cyrus, the Jonas Brothers, Bruce Springsteen, and Pink.
99
New Era
ution of tickets by various
nal Speedway
ominion
94
Similarly, the Toronto B
Major League Baseball also employ software licensed from Audien
power their self-distribution of tickets.
Rogers Centre, which seats over 49,000 fans.
96
7. International Speedway Corporation (ISC), owns 13 automobile
speedways, including tracks with capacities of 168,000 (Daytona),
(Talladega), 137,000 (Michigan), and 107,000 (Richmond).
97
Thes
numerous events, including automobile races sanctioned by NASCA
lis Racing League (IRL), as well as the Grand AmIndianapo
Association leagues. Recently, ISC purchased software from V
create a ticket distribution platform centered around Racetickets.
8. Comcast Corporation employs Paciolan software to power
Ticketing Subsidiary, which distributes tickets for venues owned
such as Philadelphia’s Wachovia Center, which seats 21,600 for bas
18,000 for hockey.
98
The Center also hosts numerous concerts
entertainers. In 2009 alone the following artists performed at t
Center or are scheduled to do so later in the year: Beyonce, Eri
also provides technological support for the distrib
venues not owned by Comcast, including the Dover Internatio
(135,000); the Portland Rose Quarter, and Constant Center at Old D
rchase of
University of
Bank Stadium, http://stadium.gophersports.com/
t_the_stadium.html (last visited Sept. 9, 2009) (report that capacity of new TCF
of Minnesota
last visited
s 14,625).
er_list.asp (last
mlb_2790 (last
oviding information about Rogers Centre and its environs).
97
See ISC: A Motorsports Entertainment Co., http://ir.iscmotorsports.com/phoenix.
zhtml?c=113983&p=irol-facilities (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
98
See Online Seats.com, http://www.onlineseats.com/venue/wachovia-center.htm (last
visited Sept. 9, 2009). Comcast also owned the famous Philadelphia Spectrum, which
was recently demolished.
99
See Wachovia Center, http://www.wachoviacenter.com/events/calendar_calendar
View.asp (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
University of Minnesota, Buy Tickets, https://www.tickets.umn.edu/
AudienceViewSplash/ (last visited Sept. 9, 2009) (“Shopping Cart for pu
Minnesota Gophers tickets states Powered By AudienceView Ticketing”) ;
Minnesota’s TCF
abou
Bank stadium, will be 50,000) ; GopherSports.com: The Official Website
Athletics, www.gophersports.com/ViewArticle.dbml?&ATCLID=310102 (
Sept. 9, 2009) (reporting current capacity of Williams basketball arena a
94
See supra note 93 at http://www.audienceview.com/customers/custom
visited Sept. 9, 2009).
95
Id.
96
See ESPN, http://sports.espn.go.com/travel/stadium/index?stadium=
visited Sept. 9, 2009) (page pr
37
University (capacity of 9,500).
100
The Rose Quarter is hom
which seats over 20,000 fans for basketball, and is home to the Port
Trailblazers and Portland Winterhawks. The venue also hosts nume
and other events, including, in 2009 alone: The Jonas Brothers, Ke
Dylan, Earth Wind and Fire, Killers, Miley Cyrus, Billy Joel and Elton Joh
Ringling Brothers and Barnum and Bailey Circus, religious f
e to the Rose Garden,
land
rous concerts
ith Urban, Bob
n, the
igure Joel Osteen,
ers.
101
, then an
tribution of
tribute tickets
nment venues that outsource their ticket
to distribute
cketReturn to power
ham Bulls, Akron
, Memphis
ges and
bution,
ersity, Liberty
n Francisco, and
eturn platform
University of South Carolina, Georgia Tech, North Carolina State, and West
Virginia University. Like Veritix, Front Gate, AudienceView and others,
ncluding the
and their entertainment
Disney on Ice, and “So You Think You Can Dance,” among oth
9. In 2005 Major League Baseball (“MLB”) purchased Tickets.com
independent distributor of tickets. Tickets.com now powers the dis
tickets for several major league baseball teams and continues to dis
for numerous other sports and entertai
distribution. The firm also offers its technology to venues that wish
their tickets in house.
102
10. More than fifty minor league baseball teams rely upon Ti
their self-distribution of tickets.
103
These teams include the Dur
Racers, Kansas City T-Bones, Lexington Legends, Toledo Mudhens
Redbirds, Charlotte Knights, and San Jose Giants. Numerous colle
universities also rely upon TicketReturn to support their ticket distri
including Appalachian State University, Western Carolina Univ
University, Christopher Newport University, the University of Sa
William and Mary.
104
Several larger institutions employ a TicketR
to power their student ticketing operations, including the University of Maryland,
TicketReturn offers a wide variety of support to venues it serves, i
ability to gather and synthesize data about individual fans
preferences.
105
100
See New Era Ticketing, http://www.neweratickets.com/our-clients/o
list/
ur-clients/client-
Office
rter,
last visited Sept. 9,
at Safeway
me/TicketOutlets/tabid/58/Default.aspx (last visited Sept. 9,
is powered by “CoxTix,” the
wered by Paciolan and New Era Tickets.”
101
See id. at http://www.rosequarter.com/ (last visited Sept. 9, 2009).
102
See http://provenue.tickets.com/US/ticketing_solutions/index.shtml (discussing
“ProvenueMax, an in- house licensed ticketing system”).
103
See https://www.ticketreturn.com/prod2/customerspro.asp (listing the firm’s
Professional Sports clients).
104
See https://www.ticketreturn.com/prod2/customerscollege.asp.
105
TicketReturn’s Website claims:
(last visited Sept.9, 2009); http://www.rosequarter.com/Home/Box
/tabid/56/Default.aspx (last visited Sept. 9, 2009); Rose Qua
http://www.rosequarter.com/Home/BoxOffice/tabid/56/Default.aspx (
2009). The Rose Quarter also lists fifty-six retail ticket outlets, most of them
Supermarkets in the Portland area. See id. at
www.rosequarter.com/Ho
2009). Although the Constant Center advertises that it
website indicates that it is “Po
38
11. Over a decade ago the New York Metropolitan Opera develope
launched its “Impresario” ticketing system de novo.
d and
ly thereafter the Met
ogy to
n-profit
ding the Met,
nedy Center, the
ive foreign
nternet
t)” as well as
memberships,
utive information
irm apparently
site includes a
’s attributes and capabilities to those of for-profit
icant client, the
ch had distributed
ion before it, is
n ives to Ticketmaster. The report indicates that AEG is
considering both distributors, such as Veritix and Tickets.com, as well as self-
that AEG has
et for ticket
106
Short
renamed the system “Tessitura” and formed a non-profit Limited Liability
Company to own the new ticketing platform and license the technol
others.
107
By 2002, the LLC had evolved into a licensee-owned no
corporation formed under Delaware law, with owner-licensees inclu
the Chicago Lyric Opera, the San Francisco Symphony, the Ken
Seattle and Santa Fe Operas and nineteen other licensees. Today the entity boasts
188 licensees and at least 80 sublicenses in the United States and f
countries. The Tessitura system promises to provide “full no fee I
transactional capability for ticketing (including select your own sea
support for “customer relationship management,” “fundraising,
sponsorships and contributions,” and “flexible reporting, exec
and analysis tools.”
108
Although a “not for profit” enterprise, the f
considers itself a rival to commercial ticketing firms, as its Web
chart comparing Tessitura
technology firms.
109
Indeed, just recently, the firm won a signif
Tennessee Performing Arts Center, from Ticketmaster, whi
tickets for the Center for 29 years.
110
12. Bloomberg.com recently reported that AEG, like Live Nat
exploring alter at
distribution strategies. One industry analyst said of AEG’s move
“the ability to instantly become a viable competitor” in the mark
distribution services.
111
stems put you
ch with customers and their ticket usage habits. Sell and deliver print at
; Automate the return of unused seats;
ce history;
Automate attendance
inate audits of paper ticket stubs;
iles for every
a timeline of
).
107
See id.
108
See http://www.tessituranetwork.com/Products/Software.aspx.
109
See http://www.tessituranetwork.com/en/Products/~/media/Public Site/Tessitura
Software Industry Comparison_2008.ashx.
110
See TPAC Dumps Ticketmaster After 29 Years, NASHVILLE BUS. J., July 1, 2009,
available at: http://nashville.bizjournals.com/nashville/stories/2009/06/29/daily23.html.
111
Ticketmaster Client AEG Said to Explore new Partner, Bloomberg.com, Nov. 2, 2009.
TicketReturn’s exclusive barcoding and Fanticket management
in tou
sy
home e-tickets online; Target no-shows
Reward your most loyal fans; E-mail customers based on attendan
Develop qualified sales leads from pass-along ticket users;
counts with real time admission reporting; Elim
Track ticket ownership changes online; Create ticket usage prof
customer.
See https://www.ticketreturn.com/prod2/customers.html.
106
See http://www.tessituranetwork.com/About/Timeline.aspx (providing
the development and widespread adoption of the Tessitura ticketing platform
39
technological and commercial feasibility of a venue, whether large or mo
vertically integrate into the self-provision of ticket distribution services.
trend toward such integration strongly suggests that combining previously s
functions produces efficiencies not realizable through market contracting
there any reason to believe that these examples are idiosyncratic or that th
These various examples—and there are more—demonstrate, at a minimum, the
re modest, to
112
Indeed, the
eparate
.
113
Nor is
e capacity for
such integration in the future is somehow limited. The necessary technology for such
d that self-
iscipline any
possible exercise of market power by firms like Ticketmaster.
115
We would expect this
xt few years.
114
integration is more available now than just a few years ago, when a federal court—in the
course of rejecting an antitrust suit against Ticketmaster—all but predicte
distribution would take on increased significance in the near future and d
trend to accelerate as more ticket distribution contracts expire over the ne
112
See Ticketmaster Corp. v. Tickets.com, Inc., 2003-1 Trade Cas. (CCH)
96,241 (C.D. Cal. 2003) (explaining that numerous colleges and universiti
self-distribution).
113
See infra Part IV.3.
114
See generally SunGard, 172 F. Supp. at 190-91 (asking whether custo
would switch in response to a hypothetical price increase were truly represe
custo
¶ 74,013, at
es rely upon
mers who
ntative of the
most of the
e in this
, 850 F.2d
espond to SSNPI
tive customers
115
It should be noted in this connection that contracts between software providers and
venues are generally non-exclusive, i.e., do not preclude the licensor from licensing the
same ticket distribution platform to other venues or, for that matter, preclude the venue
from employing that platform to distribute tickets to events at other venues. For instance,
New Era Tickets, a subsidiary of Comcast, both relies upon Paciolan technology to
distribute tickets for events at Comcast-owned venues and, in addition, licenses the same
technology to unrelated venues to facilitate their self-distribution. In any event, for the
mer population as a whole); Cardinal Health, 12 F. Supp. 2d at 48-50 (holding that
vertical integration would not defeat a hypothetical price increase because
hypothetical monopolist’s customers did not have the capacity to integrat
fashion); FTC v. Owens-Illinois, Inc., 681 F. Supp. 27, 37, vacated as moot
694 (D.D.C 1988) (fact that a trivial number of customers would not r
did not establish relevant product market where numerous more representa
would).
40
Indeed, the line between “outsourced” distribution, by agents such as
instance,
e of its rivals retain
ox office
edly engaged in
self-distribution nonetheless still outsource key aspects of the distribution function to
116
erous firms —
h venue a
h venue selects
dle that may be
h firms also
offer software options that empower venues—whether engaged in outsourcing or self-
distribution—to gather and synthesize data for the purpose of better understanding the
y services.
s agent, as
managing
self-distribution
Ticketmaster, on the one hand, and “self distribution” supported and enabled by
independent technology providers, on the other, is by no means bright. For
many venues that “outsource” ticket distribution to Ticketmaster or on
the right and ability to distribute some tickets themselves, often from the b
and/or to season ticket holders. At the same time, many venues purport
third parties, including technology providers themselves. In truth, num
Ticketmaster, Tickets.com, Veritix, AudienceView, and others—offer eac
cafeteria-style menu of distribution options and related services, and eac
the particular bundle that suits its needs at the time of contracting, a bun
adjusted as a venue’s needs and/or capabilities evolve. Moreover, all suc
characteristics of fans and the preferences for entertainment and ancillar
Importantly, whether a firm offers to distribute tickets as a venue’
Ticketmaster does, or instead enable a venue to distribute tickets itself, both services
achieve the same functions of distributing tickets to fans and collecting and
related information. It is therefore not surprising that firms that enable
e, as do the Guidelines, that self-distribution is
infinitely available at current (per-merger) prices. See Joint Merger Guidelines § 1.11, n.
9.
116
For instance, firms such as Veritix that focus on facilitating self-distribution also
provide server capacity for venues that choose not to own and operate such capacity
themselves. Such firms may also provide or recommend equipment that scans barcoded
tickets, for instance, as well as assistance processing credit card transactions. See
https://www.ticketreturn.com/prod2/faq.html.
purpose of market definition, we assum
41
effectively bid against firms like Ticketmaster when a distribution contract has expired
117
The overlap
ble self
distribution
er, itself militates in favor of a finding that both firms occupy the
sam
To be sure, it is unlikely that all venues would pursue self-distribution strategies
riety of
and not-for-
f those venues
we are not
aware of any particular types or categories of venue for which such integration would be
especially difficult or costly, thereby exposing such venues to selective price increases by
a hypothetical monopolist.
119
As a result, substitution by a even a modest number of
hereby
and a venue is tempted to forgo outsourcing in favor of self-distribution.
and real world rivalry between the services provided by “firms that ena
distribution,” on the one hand, and those that provide “outsourced ticket
services,” on the oth
e product market.
118
in response to a SSNIP by a hypothetical monopolist of outsourced ticket distribution
services. Nonetheless, the successful vertical integration by such a wide va
venues—large, small, and medium, sports, musical and mixed use, profit
profit—suggests that the option is in fact a realistic one for most if not all o
that still outsource the distribution of most or all of their tickets. Moreover,
venues would render a small but significant price increase unprofitable, t
protecting any venues that may be less price sensitive.
120
117
See Ticketmaster, 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241 (finding that “virtually all long term
rms that
ketmaster that
118
Id. at 96,241-42.
119
Cf. Cardinal Health, 12 F. Supp. 2d at 36-49 (finding that prospect of self-
distribution by large drug store chains would not protect small “Mom and Pop” chains
from a hypothesized price increase).
120
See United States v. Engelhard Corp., 126 F.3d 1302, 1306 (11th Cir. 1997) (“[I]t is
possible for only a few customers who switch to alternatives to make the price increase
unprofitable. . . .”); SunGard, 172 F. Supp. 2d at 193 (finding broader market even
contracts are awarded after some form of bidding competition” and that fi
support and enable self-distribution are a “viable option” to firms like Tic
distribute tickets for firms that choose to outsource this task).
42
Equally important, antitrust principles and legal authority readily support the
vertical integration
e task of
reaten to do so as a
market
definition itself, various courts have recognized that “captive production” resulting from
vertical integration can be a clos d might thereby
122
ces” must
include not only outsourced ticket distribution services, such as those provided by
uld provide
treatment of such integration as a close substitute for outsourced ticket distribution
services. More than two decades ago, a leading jurist explained that “
is a universal feature of economic life,” and that firms frequently take on th
distributing their own product to displace an inefficient supplier or th
means of holding down the cost of outsourced inputs.
121
When it comes to
e substitute for outsourced production an
prevent independent producers from exercising market power.
Therefore, a properly defined market for “ticket distribution servi
Ticketmaster and similar firms, but also distribution services that venues co
vernment] is
698, 710 (7th Cir.
cturer to take
laces
t if they charge too
. R.H. Coase,
uction of
e included in
ork in-house in
172 (asking
crease were
customer population as a whole); Cardinal Health, 12 Supp. 2d
at 48 (declining to include potential captive production in the relevant market because
most customers would not, in fact, view such vertical integration as a plausible substitute
for their current practice of purchasing supplies directly from wholesalers). See also
Geraldine Alpert & Howard P. Kitt, Is Structure All?, 53 A
NTITRUST L.J. 255, 266-67
(1984) (contending that “do-it-yourself” or “make or buy” options are often plausible
substitutes for purchase of putative product on the open market and thus can be properly
included in the relevant market).
though “the demand of some customers [for the product identified by the go
inelastic”).
121
See generally Jack Walters & Sons v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d
1984) (Posner, J.) (“A common type of vertical integration is for a manufa
over the distribution of his product.… [T]he option of vertical integration p
competitive pressure on the firm’s suppliers and buyers, who know tha
much for their services the firm may decide to perform them itself.”). Cf
The Nature of the Firm, 4 E
CONOMICA 381 (1932).
122
Grumman Corp., 665 F.2d at 13-14 (holding that potential captive prod
aircraft subassemblies by Boeing and McDonald Douglas would properly b
relevant product market if such manufacturers would in fact bring such w
response to significant price increases by subcontractors); SunGard., at
whether customers who would switch in response to a hypothetical price in
truly representative of the
43
for themselves by licensing or purchasing technology from firms that support such
123
port for such
ult for any
category of
rice increase.
Unlike some industries, the ticket distribution industry is not characterized by network
at could hamper
arket is simply not
culation of market
sha
Identification of Market Participants and Calculation of Market Shares
Following the definition of the relevant market, a challenger to a merger must also
rket shares of
ster, Etix.com, Tickets.com, Frontgate,
distribution. Given the current dynamic and rapidly evolving technological landscape,
including the ready availability of licensing technology and other sup
vertical integration, one might therefore conclude that it would be diffic
hypothetical monopolist of outsourced ticket distribution services for any
venues or promoters to profitably maintain a significant, non-transitory p
effects that could entrench or protect a dominant firm in the face of vertical integration by
venues. Nor are we aware of any plausible exclusionary practices th
competitive challenges to incumbents.
124
Perhaps, then, the m
“monopolizeable,” and our inquiry need not proceed to the cal
res.
125
We nonetheless proceed with the complete horizontal analysis.
establish which firms participate in that relevant market and the relative ma
such firms.
126
Obviously firms such as Ticketma
123
Testimony of Luke Froeb before the House Subcommittee on Courts
Policy, 5-6 (February 26, 2009) (treating firms such as Veritix and Audienc
participants in the same product market as Ticketmaster).
124
See infra notes 169-171 and accompanying text (explaining why exclus
arrangements between venues and ticket providers are not plaus
and Competition
eView as
ive
ible methods of raising
125
See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34, 82-84 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc)
(per curiam) (ease of entry into browser market suggests the market is not
monopolizeable and supracompetitive pricing is not possible, even for a provider with an
extremely large market share). Cf. United States v. Gen. Dynamics, 415 U.S. 486, 510-
511 (1974) (declining to entertain government’s appeal of district court’s product market
definition because government’s case would fail under any such definition).
126
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, supra note 51, § 1.3.
rivals’ costs and entrenching monopoly).
44
Metrotix.com, TicketWeb.com, and Tele-charge, participate in the market as defined
ents and
127
with other
ple,
g needs of
t would be
providing ticket distribution services for venues that chose to outsource such distribution.
amic responses to price changes by venues that
hav the potential growth
of vertical
integration: (1) integration that has already occurred before the transaction that is under
review, such as the numerous examples listed above, and (2) integration that might
potentially take place after such a transaction. Ironically, venues that engaged in self-
ive Nation,
because they each distribute tickets on behalf of venues that host large ev
outsource ticket distribution. It is also clear that any venues that contract
venues to provide ticket distribution services also participate in the market. For exam
should Live Nation’s own ticket distribution operation service the ticketin
venues managed by SMG, it would clearly be a market participant because i
The more difficult market share determinations involve assessing the extent of self-
ticketing before the transaction, the dyn
e already vertically integrated into ticket distribution, as well as
of additional self-ticketing in the near future.
128
It is useful at the outset to distinguish between two categories
distribution before this transaction, including those owned or operated by L
127
Some of these firms, of course, also distribute tickets for venues they o
but this fact does not militate against their inclusion in the market for ticket dis
services to the extent that they do, in fact, perform this function.
128
We pause here to note that our conclusions regarding market de
wn or control,
tribution
finition, the
identification of participants in the relevant market, and the (unlikely) prospect of
coordinated or unilateral anticompetitive effects do not turn on any determination that
technology companies that support self-distribution are properly treated as market
participants within the taxonomy employed by current merger law. Whether or not such
firms are technically “in” the relevant product market, they certainly provide inputs that
facilitate and encourage venues’ self-distribution of tickets, and such self-distribution
appears to be a reasonable substitute for outsourced ticket distribution services.
45
are arguably less likely to be meaningful participants in the relevant market than those
venues that m
internal or captive
at it is
e market in
er.
129
Moreover,
merger law has long recognized that a firm’s nominal output of a product does not by
ere,
s by contract,
arketplace has no competitive significance, and a merger
of t the nominal
Here “captive production” generally consists of a venue’s distribution of tickets to
owns or
oduction to a
ight so integrate in the future.
As the enforcement agencies have themselves emphasized,
production should be included in the relevant market only to the extent th
economically meaningful, that is, could alter the competitive dynamics of th
response to collusive behavior or a monopolistic exercise of market pow
itself establish the magnitude of the firm’s competitive significance. For instance, wh
before a merger, a firm’s future output is committed to particular customer
removal of that firm from the m
hat firm with another does not, in fact, reduce competition, regardless of
level of concentration that results.
130
its own events, or a promoter’s distribution of tickets to events at venues it
operates. It is not obvious how venues or promoters could divert such pr
129
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, §1.31 (vertically-integrated fi
as participants in relevant market “to the extent that such inclusion a
their competitive significance in the relevant market before the merger”);
Federal Trade Commission, FTC v. Cardinal Health, Nos. 98-595 & 98-59
(same). See also 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 2.23
vertically integrated firms would shift internal production to relevan
participate via
rms will be included
ccurately reflects
Brief for the
6, at 14-15
(asking whether
t market or
downstream competition in response to a small but significant non-
ede the
believe that § 2.23 of
the 1984 Guidelines states the appropriate methodology for determining whether in fact
captive production is properly considered part of the relevant market. Indeed, the 1992
Joint Merger Guidelines employ such an analysis to identify firms outside the relevant
market that may “participate through supply responses.” See 1992 Joint Merger
Guidelines § 1.32.
130
See Gen. Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 501-510; Ball Mem’l Hosp. v. Mut. Hosp. Ins. Co.,
784 F.2d 1325, 1336 (7th Cir. 1985) (explaining rationale of Gen. Dynamics).
transitory price increase). The 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines supers
corresponding portions of the 1984 Guidelines. Nonetheless, we
46
properly defined distribution market in response to a hypothesized price increase (the
ket!).
131
Thus,
is reserved by
petitive
tsource. Live
Nation, of course, is one firm with significant “captive production” of ticket distribution
y of the data
ting
se by venues the
e in any economically
meaningful sense to third-party venues that seek to outsource the distribution of their
tickets, it is unlikely to significantly affect the relevant market and thus is not a
meaningful substitute for venues that outsource their ticket distribution.
133
Vertically integrated firms could, however, participate in the relevant market if
they would respond to a price increas
Houston Rockets, for instance, will not suspend their home games so the Houston Toyota
Center can somehow divert its self-distribution of tickets to the open mar
because the pre-merger captive production of ticket distribution services
definition for venues themselves, such production does not have the same com
significance as services available for purchase by venues that choose to ou
services, given that it distributes tickets for events at the numerous venues it owns or
operates as well as events it promotes at independent venues. Indeed, man
purporting to show that Live Nation is a significant participant in the ticke
distribution market in fact refer to such captive production for internal u
firm owns or manages.
132
Because such production is not availabl
e imposed by a hypothetical monopolist of
131
By contrast, one can certainly imagine, say, a vertically-integrated power company
that relies on plants fueled by natural gas and coal reducing its reliance on gas and
diverting such gas into the “spot” market in response to a significant price increase in that
market.
132
See Kohl Letter, supra note 4 (asserting that Live Nation “start[ed] a ticketing
business to compete with Ticketmaster (and as a result sold 5.8 million tickets in the first
four months of 2009). If the merger occurs, this direct competition will be lost.”).
133
Cf. Gen. Dynamics, 415 U.S. 486.
47
outsourced ticket distribution services. For instance, such firms could expand the
135
and their own
necessarily entail increased
pro
e in one or
both of these ways, then it would be appropriate to attribute such incremental, expanded
rket
ting a firm’s captive
ution to a
responses is
ppears to be the
motivation behind the vertical integration that has already occurred. As explained
previously, such integration appears to be an effort by promoters, venues, and artists to
for instance,
tainment
134
scope of their distribution activities beyond their own venues, taking on the task of
distributing tickets for other venues as well. Such firms could also exp
downstream output of entertainment services, which would
duction of inputs to such services, including ticket distribution.
136
If vertically integrated firms respond to a hypothetical price increas
output to the relevant market for the purpose of determining overall ma
concentration. However, such a finding might still not justify attribu
production to that market due to that firm’s inability to “sell” its self-distrib
venue that outsources it ticket distribution. Although either of these
possible, we think they are unlikely for any given venue in light of what a
capture efficiencies from marketing live entertainment directly to fans, by,
facilitating the production and synthesis of information about fans’ enter
134
See SunGard, 172 F. Supp. 2d at 186, n.14, quoting P. AREEDA, IIA AN
¶ 535e (1995) (citing 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, § 1.31); 1984 Departm
Merger Guidelines, §2.23 (“Captive production and consumption of the relevant product
TITRUST LAW,
ent of Justice
arket supply and demand. Such
e of two ways.
lternatively,
of their production but increase their production of
both the relevant product and products in which the relevant product is embodied. Either
kind of supply response could frustrate collusion by firms currently selling the relevant
product.”).
135
See 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 2.23.
136
See 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines,§ 2.23. See generally 1992 Joint
Merger Guidelines, § 1.11 (treating presence of downstream competition as a factor that
can defeat a hypothetical price increase).
by vertically integrated firms are part of the overall m
firms may respond to an increase in the price of the relevant product in on
They may begin selling the relevant product [i.e., in the open market], or a
they may continue to consume all
48
preferences. It does not appear to be an independent effort to profit from ticket
such
Live Nation, have
ey are not
. It seems
ent if the cost
of ticket distribution changes, especially because artists, more than venues or promoters,
r ticket
ase by vertically
by meriting
ination to
make for any particular venue, especially because the trend towards vertical integration
appears to be accelerating independent of any hypothesized price increase (and, in fact, in
138
ntify with
certainty the many firms that supply the technology and other inputs necessary to
ate, Showare,
g in this list
distribution in the same way that Ticketmaster or Tickets.com seek to profit from
distribution. While there may be vertically integrated firms that, like
endeavored to provide ticket distribution services for venues to which th
otherwise related, these firms appear to be the exception rather than the rule
similarly unlikely that venues would increase their output of live entertainm
are the primary drivers of output.
More significant is whether venues that currently outsource thei
distribution services would respond to a small but significant price incre
integrating and taking on the task of distributing tickets themselves, there
treatment as participants in the relevant market.
137
This is a difficult determ
the face of reportedly steadily declining prices). We can, however, ide
vertically integrate in this manner, such as Veritix, AudienceView, Front G
TicketReturn, Tessitura, and Tickets.com (Paciolan would otherwise belon
137
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, § 1.31. See also SunGard, 172 F. Supp. 2d at 187
(“[W]hat is significant is not whether the companies that currently use inter
have the capacity to e
nal solutions
nter the market as vendors for others, but whether the customers
that currently use [outsourced] hotsites would switch to an internal hotsite [i.e., vertically
integrate] in response to a SSNIP.”). Some may argue that such firms are better
characterized as “firms that participate through supply responses.” See 1992 Joint
Merger Guidelines, §§ 1.31, 1.321 & 1.322.
138
Alpert & Kitt, supra note 122, at 266-67 (noting difficulty of calculating market
concentration where “do-it-yourself” production is a meaningful substitute for purchasing
input on the open market).
49
but is now owned by Ticketmaster). These firms could be included as participants in the
uestion is whether the
a
as become, and as
determine the exact degree of additional post-
merger vertical integration with any certainty.
cludes
New Era’s
has a market
en hands-down
s ion services—or,
more precisely, the quantity of tickets distributed—have been used by opponents of the
proposed merger to assert that Ticketmaster dominates the relevant market.
140
But
arguably such data do not accurately reflect the underlying competitive and economic
realities in the industry. Both courts and the antitrust enforcement agencies have
repeatedly stated that reliance upon historical unit sales is merely one of several methods
relevant product market as proxies for anticipated increases in vertical integration and
assign them market shares accordingly. Here again the central q
actual or potential captive production would be forthcoming in response to
hypothesized price increase.
139
As widespread as vertical integration h
likely as it is to spread, it is difficult to
Within these parameters, a current market share calculation—whether it in
all or part or none of Live Nation’s captive production, whether it includes
growth outside Comcast venues, etc.—would indicate that Ticketmaster
share far larger than its rivals. There is no doubt that Ticketmaster has be
the industry leader, and historical measures of sales of ticket di tribut
139
See 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 2.23 (asking whether vertically
integrated firms would shift internal production to relevant market or participate via
downstream competition in response to a small but significant non-transitory price
increase). See also 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines § 1.32 (articulating similar test for
identifying “firms that participate [in the relevant market] through supply responses”).
140
See supra note 28 with TicketNews scores and other data sources approximating
market shares.
50
of determining firms’ respective shares of the relevant market and may, in fact, result in a
misleading a
141
lf-distribution.
ution software (a
historical sales
Perhaps most
important, the competitive bidding process that venues use to solicit competition
focused competition
ircumstances such
, the merger
e on historical
market shares and instead rely upon the capacity of individual firms to provide the
s expressly
ssessment of the competitive consequences of a transaction.
To begin with, historical sales ignore venues’ ability to switch to se
Moreover, because the marginal costs of licensing Internet ticket distrib
non-rival good) is obviously low, participants’ capacity and not their
provides a more accurate estimate of overall market concentration.
following the expiration of distribution contracts creates moments of
that dull any advantages of incumbency or historical market share. In c
as these, in which all market participants have equal access to buyers
guidelines adopted by the antitrust enforcement agencies abjure relianc
service in question as the appropriate market shares.
142
These Guideline
141
Joint Merger Guidelines § 1.521 ("[R]ecent or ongoing changes in the m
indicate that the current market share of a particular firm either unders
the firm's future competitive significance. . . . The Agency will consider rea
predictable effects of recent or ongoing changes in market conditions in
[historical] market concentration and market share data. "); Brown Shoe C
States, 370 U.S. 294, 322 n.38 (1962) ("Statistics reflecting the shar
controlled by the industry leaders and the parties to the merger are, o
index of market power; but only a further examination of the particular m
structure, history and probable future – ca
arket may
tates or overstates
sonably
interpreting
o. v. United
es of the market
f course, the primary
arket – its
n provide the appropriate setting for judging the
84 U.S. Dist.
e capacity" as "the
appropriate statistical basis for measurement of future industry competitive
performance"); FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d 109, 128 (D.D.C. 2004)
(identifying reserves, loadout capacity, and production and practical capacity "all
informative to some degree, yet . . . imperfect" indicators of future ability to compete,"
and therefore, considering all measures together)..
142
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines, § 1.41 (“Calculating Market Shares: General
Approach”); id. (“Physical capacity or reserves generally will be used [to measure
probable anticompetitive effect of the merger."); FTC v. Bass Bros., 19
LEXIS 16122, *19 (N.D. Ohio June 6, 1984) (identifying "productiv
51
provide that, “[w]here all firms have, on a forward-looking basis, an equal likelihood of
143
ent of Justice
ee bidders
tmaster to provide
ch as Veritix,
AudienceView, Frontgate, Tessitura, TicketReturn, and others can bid for the right to
HI much lower
ived from historical market shares, regardless of the number of venues that
wou summation of
Consequently, the identification of market participants and market shares brings
the inquiry back to the original question of how easily a venue can acquire the Internet
ndustry suggest that
vertical integration is becoming both increasingly inexpensive and otherwise desirable,
uch a strategy.
both to
securing sales, the Agency will assign firms equal shares.” The Departm
has even gone so far as to argue—successfully—that the presence of thr
suffices to ensure sufficient competition for the right to publish a state’s official legal
reports.
144
Firms such as Tickets.com can bid head to head with Ticke
outsourced ticket distribution services,
145
and at the same time, firms su
provide technology that enables a venue to forgo outsourcing in favor of self-distribution.
As a result, a capacity-based approach in this context would result in an H
than that der
ld, in fact, vertically integrate into ticket distribution shortly after con
this transaction.
technology required to self-distribute tickets. Developments in the i
such that venues could counteract any monopoly pricing by pursuing s
Ultimately, assessing the practicability of vertical integration is necessary
.”). See also
oint Merger Guidelines, § 1.41 (“Calculating Market Shares: General
Approach”), n. 15.
144
See The Thomson Corp., 949 F. Supp. 907, 919 (approving consent decree that did
not order divestiture of publishing contracts for the state of Washington because presence
of two other publishers capable of bidding for the right to publish Washington official
reports would, as the government argued, “ensure vigorous competition in Washington”).
145
See Ticketmaster Corp. v. Tickets.com, 2003-1 Trade Cas. ¶ 74,013, at 96,240-41
(C.D. Cal.2003).
concentration] if it is these measures that most effectively distinguish firms
United States v. Thomson Corp., 949 F. Supp. 907, 919 (D.D.C. 1996).
143
See 1992 J
52
properly define the market and to arrive at meaningful measures of market concentration
Pot
ated that calculation
uences.
146
The
enforcement agencies in particular have recently cautioned against “undue emphasis on
erger analysis
147
ach, enshrined in
forcement
otential post-
merger harms: “coordinated interaction,” whereby remaining participants in the industry
hereby the
and power.
ential Adverse Effects
Both courts and the enforcement agencies have repeatedly st
of market shares and resulting concentration ratios is simply a “starting point” in
determining whether a merger will likely result in anticompetitive conseq
market share and concentration statistics” as opposed to application of m
“as an integrated whole to case-specific facts.” That integrated appro
the Horizontal Merger Guidelines and employed by both courts and the en
agencies, involves investigating and assessing the risk of two particular p
“pursue parallel policies of mutual advantage,”
148
and “unilateral effects,” w
146
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.0 (“Other things being equal, market
affects the likelihood that one firm, or a small group of firms, could successfully exercise
market power. . . . However, market share and concentration data pro
starting point for analyzing the competitive impact of a merger.”); Depart
and Federal Trade Commission Commentary on Joint Merger Guid
agencies have often not challenged mergers involving market shares an
that fall outside the [safe harbors] set forth in Guidelines § 1.51. This d
concentration
vide only the
ment of Justice
elines, at 15-16 (“The
d concentration
oes not mean the
ares and
‘starting point’ and that many mergers falling outside these
onsideration
ssen
specific
facts—not undue emphasis on market share and concentration statistics—determines
whether the Agency will challenge a particular merger.”).
147
See Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Commentary on Joint
Merger Guidelines, at 15-16.
148
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.S. 271, 280 (1964); FTC v. Heinz
Co., 246 F.3d 708, 715 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (“Merger law ‘rests upon the theory that, where
rivals are few, firms will be able to coordinate their behavior, either by overt collusion or
[concentration thresholds] are not meaningful, but rather that market sh
concentration are but a
concentration zones [i.e., in concentrated markets] nevertheless, upon full c
of the factual and economic evidence, are found unlikely substantially to le
competition. Application of the Guidelines as an integrated whole to case-
53
firm created by the merger itself exercises market power after the transaction, without
regard to the reaction of other
149
t Distribution
ticipants are
d on historical
aracterized as
moderately or highly concentrated. We might proceed with the additional assumption,
bona fide arket participant (and
ith committed
ith
ption under
f market power.
150
Even if one were to make these various assumptions, the structure of the market for ticket
distribution services and the nature of the rivalry that takes place within it make it
unlikely that the merger will facilitate either coordinated interaction or unilateral actions
that create market power to the detriment of purchasers.
participants in the marketplace.
We assume for the sake of argument a relevant market of “Ticke
Services for Large Venues” and also assume that, regardless of which par
included in that market, Ticketmaster has a substantial market share base
sales as a clear market leader and, moreover, that the market would be ch
again for the sake of argument, that Live Nation is a m
not, as we think more likely, far better viewed as an integrated producer w
output) and that Live Nation’s output is significant enough that a merger w
Ticketmaster would increase market concentration enough to raise a presum
the Merger Guidelines that the merger would facilitate the exercise o
ove competitive
Cir. 1986); Joint
Merger Guidelines, § 2.1 (describing theory of coordinated interaction).
149
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.2.
150
See Joint Merger Guidelines § 1.51 (b) (mergers that increase HHI less than 100
points in moderately concentrated market “are unlikely to have adverse competitive
consequences and ordinarily require no further analysis”); id. at 151(c) (mergers that
increase HHI less than 50 points in highly concentrated market “are unlikely to have
adverse competitive consequences and ordinarily require no further analysis”).
implicit understanding, in order to restrict output and achieve profits ab
levels.’") quoting FTC v. PPG Indus., 798 F.2d 1500, 1503 (D.C.
54
We are of course aware that some opponents to the transaction have claimed that
erger to monopoly.
151
n and self-
cus on a
iter—that is
efinition of the
market, which recognizes and incorporates the potential for vertical integration and self-
erous
follow the template
of t turn first to examine whether the transaction will lead to
“co ely define it.
1. Coordinated Interaction
To be successful, coordinated interaction requires participants in a collusive
t to
erstanding is
ous and sold at a
stances,
onitor each
ervices are not
the combination of Live Nation and Ticketmaster is effectively a m
Such arguments, however, ignore the availability of vertical integratio
distribution as substitutes for outsourced distribution, and thus narrowly fo
segment of the market—outsourced distribution of ticketing services simplic
not economically meaningful for antitrust analysis. A more appropriate d
distribution, offers strong counterarguments to the claim that the proposed transaction
will produce market power. With this in mind, and recognizing that num
independent firms provide and support ticket distribution services, we
he Merger Guidelines and
ordinated interaction” in the market as we believe courts would lik
scheme, at a minimum, to reach a mutual understanding regarding the price and outpu
which parties to the understanding will purportedly adhere. Such an und
easiest when the product or service provided by the parties is homogene
standard price that is visible and known to all parties. Under these circum
participants in such an arrangement can readily agree on price terms and m
other’s compliance with the scheme. Where, by contrast, products or s
151
See, e.g., The Ticketmaster/Live Nation Merger: What Does it Mean for Consumers
and the Future of the Concert Business: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Competition Policy and Consumer Rights of the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 111th Cong.
3 (2009), available at: http://judiciary.senate.gov/hearings/testimony.cfm
?id=3674&wit_id=7624 [hereinafter Balto Testimony] (written testimony of David
Balto, Senior Fellow, Center for American Progress Action Fund).
55
homogenous, and where price and related terms are not observable, reaching (and
enforcing) such an understandi
152
idely and
ickets.com, venues
es to other
tance from
sophisticated technology companies, establish their own system of distribution, and firms
153
gnificant, the venues
grated firms that
nues, for
istribution
companies might provide for free or at a discount.
154
Others might require training of
box office personnel and/or assistance in deve
ng becomes much more difficult.
As was noted above, providers of ticket distribution services vary w
include traditional distribution companies, such as Ticketmaster and T
that currently engage in self-distribution and also offer distribution servic
venues, an unknown but substantial number of venues that could, with assis
that have already vertically integrated whose captive output may perhaps influence the
market even if not technically included within it. Perhaps more si
that purchase ticket distribution services, including those vertically inte
“purchase” from themselves, exhibit a wide diversity of needs. Some ve
instance, require upgrades to their computers and software, which ticket d
loping fan profiles and resulting targeted
152
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.11 (“reaching terms of coordination m
facilitated by product or firm h
ay be
al Merger
ies of various
s, including the United States, that “[c]oordination is simplified when the level of
undifferentiated
petitors to predict
153
See 2006 DOJ And FTC Commentary on the Merger Guidelines, at 15 (noting that
the Agencies will consider the impact of rivalry from products that, while technically not
in the relevant marketplace, nonetheless still exercise some competitive influence on that
market).
154
See Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,239-40 (reporting that, in some
cases, Ticketmaster provides venues with upfront cash payments to help pay for the
purchase and installation of new equipment).
omogeneity”); International Competition Network Merger
Working Group, Report on Coordinated Effects Analysis Under Internation
Regimes, ch.4 at 13 (2004) (reporting consensus among enforcement agenc
nation
product differentiation is minimal. Markets characterized by relatively
products typically involve fewer terms of sale, making it easier for com
the likely responses of their rivals.”).
56
promotional strategies. Accordingly, contracts between ticket distributors and venues,
e expectations that
156
blic and
and vertically integrated
arra
e is very
unfriendly to collusion. There is neither a single service nor a single price that can serve
the provision of that service are hidden from rivals’ view. Moreover, the process in
venues do not
155
for instance, are individually negotiated and presumably exhibit servic
are particularized for each venue. Moreover, these contracts are not pu
therefore not observable to rivals before other bids are placed,
ngements of course are completely hidden from view.
157
A market characterized by such heterogeneity and lack of disclosur
as the focus and basis of a collusive agreement, and any meaningful details that underlie
which competition plays out makes collusion additionally difficult. Large
155
For instance, Kroenke Sports Enterprises recently announced it had se
patented Flash Seats technology to power Kroenke's TicketHorse prima
lected Veritix's
ry ticketing
es to "know
ore focused
(July 1,
lease.pdf.
at such contracts
o not follow a
ities usually release
question. Such ex
t, in such a
cheme. For
ansfer price that
aring full
nology is
llustrates the variation in how ticket distribution services are
provided and the difficulty of making meaningful comparisons. See generally Coase,
supra note 121, at 381 (equating complete vertical integration with “suppression of the
price mechanism” for allocating resources). See also Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.11
(“reaching terms of coordination may be facilitated by product or firm homogeneity”)
(emphasis added); (“Firms with similar capacity, similar cost structure, common aspects
of vertical integration, similar market share, or some combination of these factors are
more likely to coordinate.”).
service, in part, because the Flash Seats technology allows teams and venu
who is in each and every seat, making marketing and customer service far m
on the actual ticket holder." Press Release, Veritix, Kroenke Sports Enterprises Selects
Flash Seats as Exclusive Digital Ticketing Provider for Venues and Events
2009), available at http://www.veritix.com/news/Kroenke_Flash_Seats_Re
156
See Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,240 (explaining th
“are negotiated at arms length between the venue and [Ticketmaster] and d
standard form. There are no contracts of adhesion.”).
157
It should be noted that publicly-owned venues and public univers
the results of a bidding process, but only after awarding the contract in
post disclosure of the terms of, say, a three to five year contract would no
dynamic industry, facilitate the actual or tacit negotiation of a collusive s
vertically integrated venues, it might even be impossible to specify the tr
corresponds to the market price for distribution services. Moreover, comp
integration with self-distribution following the licensing of Internet tech
difficult. This further i
57
simply purchase such services in small increments in a spot market but instead seek bids
paring
oviders of software
provide
manner that
or such a long-
term arrangement may itself cause firms to deviate from putative terms of coordinated
159
mediate
ral court
p of the possibility
of vertical integration by venues themselves, “is a powerful deterrent” of the exercise of
that the
for the long-term exclusive provision of such services from possible suppliers, com
the results of such bids to the cost of self-distribution enabled by pr
and expertise that support such vertical integration.
158
These conditions
purchasers with the requisite incentive to structure bidding processes in a
protects themselves from collusive bids. The prospect of winning a bid f
interaction. At the same time, the prevalence of long-term contracts that guarantee
firms a fixed amount of business may protect firms that do deviate from im
retaliation by firms seeking to enforce the tacit arrangement.
160
One fede
concluded that such a bidding process, especially against the backdro
market power by ticket distributors.
161
Other courts have also recognized
158
See Ticketmaster Corp. 2003-1 Trade Cas., at 96,239-41 (elaborating on process of
om bid against
and the time
t decided to
ernative to Ticketmaster, Live Nation “had a line-up of companies
Rapino
uld engage in
arge relative to
viate [from any
, § 2.12 (“Where detection or punishment [of deviation]
is likely to be slow, incentives to deviate are enhanced and coordinated interaction is
unlikely to be successful.”).
161
See Ticketmaster Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241 (“The bidding nature of the
competition is a powerful deterrent against the existence of monopoly power so long as
there are competitors to bid so as to give the customer an alternative.”); id. (citing cases
for the proposition that “the use of a bidding system is an indication of lack of power to
exclude competitors from the market”).
bidding for venues’ ticket distribution business and noting that Tickets.c
Ticketmaster on all 140 contracts that had become available between 1998
of the litigation). Michael Rapino, Live Nation’s CEO, testified that when i
contract with an alt
around the world that wanted to be our ticketing company.” See Michael
Tesimony, supra note 67, at 36-37.
159
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.12 (“Where large buyers likely wo
long term contracting, so that the sales covered by such contracts can be l
the total output of a firm in the market, firms may have the incentive to de
collusive agreement].”).
160
See Joint Merger Guidelines
58
existence of a bidding process can protect customers from the creation and exercise of
162
n prevent an
exe r, even in the face of a relatively concentrated marketplace.
163
and Federal
Trade Commission articulate two scenarios under which a merger that does not lead to a
arket
ns by
duce very close
rice of one such
product.
164
The second is a merger in a market where the merged firm’s rivals do not
have sufficient capacity to promptly meet a rise in demand prompted by an increase in
market power. This result is consistent with economic theory, which suggests that
properly structured bidding among a small number of potential sellers ca
rcise of market powe
2. Unilateral Effects
The enforcement guidelines employed by the Department of Justice
monopoly may nonetheless cause a unilateral exercise of market power, that is, m
power that the merged firm can profitably exploit without regard to reactio
consumers and competitors. The first is a merger between firms that pro
substitutes, thereby empowering the new entity unilaterally to raise the p
162
See Nat’l Reporting Co. v. Alderson Reporting Co., 763 F.2d 1020, 102
1985) (no dangerous probability of obtaining a monopoly for court repor
where court adopted single vendor for such service after competitive bidd
5 (8th Cir.
ting services
ing); Owens
g how customers
process and
k-Mayer, Inc. v.
6 F. Supp. 1168, 1171-72 (C.D. Cal. 1986) (no dangerous probability
nment repair and maintenance contract where
defendant obtained such contract after competitive bidding which set a fixed price, and
any renewal of such agreement would require a new round of bidding).
163
See Mary Sullivan, The Effect of the Big Eight Accounting Firm Mergers on the
Market for Audit Services, 45 J.L. & ECON. 375 (2002) (finding that two mergers by Big
Eight accounting firms did not injure purchasers of such services but instead produced
significant efficiencies).
164
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.21.
Illinois, 681 F. Supp. at 48, vacated as moot, 850 F.2d 694 (explainin
protected themselves from potential price increases by adopting a bidding
negotiating contracts requiring cost-justification for price increases); Kir
PAC ORD, Inc., 62
of obtaining monopoly over gover
59
price or reduction in output by the new entity. Neither scenario appears to be a
plausible result of the Live Na
etmaster do not appear to
y of
nues that have
g the form of
licensing technology to firms that choose to vertically integrate and engage in self-
arily
Nation
ffiliation, we
ing to be particularly
e market’s other
offerings. This could be because Live Nation (unlike Ticketmaster and its other
competitors) might not yet tailor its services to meet the specific needs of the venues it
aim unaffiliated
ticketing
tutes.
ny better. For
one thing, such a challenge would depend upon proof negating the presence of product
differentiation within the ticketi one were to stipulate the
absence of product differentiation, this theory requires demonstrating that rivals cannot
promptly respond to supracompetitive prices. However, the spread of Internet
165
tion-Ticketmaster transaction.
The first scenario is inapt because Live Nation and Tick
offer substitutable services to a common set of purchasers. The majorit
Ticketmaster’s ticketing business consists of distributing tickets for ve
chosen to outsource their ticketing distribution, with the balance takin
distribution via the firm’s Paciolan subsidiary. By contrast, Live Nation prim
distributes tickets on behalf of venues that it owns or operates. While Live
appears to now offer ticketing services to some firms with whom it has no a
are aware of no evidence that venues consider the Live Nation offer
similar to that produced by Ticketmaster, especially when compared to th
s to service. Indeed, the paucity of contracts between Live Nation and
venues makes it particularly difficult to determine whether purchasers of
services view the services offered by the merging parties to be close substi
Nor would a challenge based on rivals’ capacity limitations fare a
ng industry. Moreover, even if
165
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 2.22.
60
technologies, the non-rival nature of distribution software, and the industry’s practice of
ents in the
es would have little difficulty to vertically integrate and self-
dist
im to capitalize
on market power raises the same question, oft-repeated in this document, of how easily
hanges
chnology partner
Veritix, AudienceView, Front Gate, or TicketReturn to assume ticket distribution
itse market
power.
s of the nation’s
soliciting bids for term contracts suggest that rival ticket distributors could quickly
replace any reduction in output. And more significantly, recent developm
industry suggest that venu
ribute their own tickets.
166
Therefore, determining how the merged entity might unilaterally a
venues can acquire the requisite technology to self-distribute their tickets. If such self-
distribution alternatives are as inexpensive and attractive as recent market c
indicate—and most venues have the capacity, by partnering with a te
such as
lf—then that would negate any opportunity for a distributor to exercise
167
One alarm raised by some critics of the merger is that even if the technology for
self-distribution is widely available, Ticketmaster “controls” the busines
166
See infra note 171 and accompanying text (explaining how biddin
distribution market undermines reliance upon historical market shares as
market concentration).
167
Even some critics of the merger concede that the technology required fo
distribution is easily acquired and available from many market participants.
Robert W. Doyle, Jr., Testimony Before the U.S. House of Representativ
on the Judiciary, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy (Feb.
(stating that “[s]ome venue wi
g nature of ticket
indicators of
r self-
See e.g,
es, Committee
26, 2009)
ll explain that they have been able to set up their own
systems. The venue operators that have been successful in setting up their own system
did so by licensing software, hiring telephone operators, and opening a local box office . .
.”). To be sure, Mr. Doyle also suggested that self-ticketing is only likely when a venue
sells a large number of tickets, such as when a firm controls more than one venue or more
than one sports team. See id. at 16. Nonetheless, we have identified numerous venues
with relatively modest sales that currently distribute their own tickets. See supra notes
90, 100, 106 and accompanying text.
61
largest venues with exclusive, long-term contracts. Ticketmaster’s merger with Live
rket position.
try leadership,
hese exclusive contracts could endow the merged firm with anticompetitive market
pow
throughout the
ticketing services industry, and venues in exclusive contracts are bound to particular
169
venues are bound
ree and
ements with
expiration of
such agreements, the venue typically invites proposals from several different ticketing
service and technology providers, initiating a competitive bargaining process for a new
o Ticketmaster,
ploying technology supplied by
cipation of the
icketmaster. This competitive bidding process is pitting
168
Nation, these critics fear, would further enshrine Ticketmaster’s current ma
If rivals and potential entrants are unable to challenge Ticketmaster’s indus
then t
er.
Although exclusive contracts appear to be commonly employed
distributors by contracts of varying lengths, it is easy to overestimate the impact of such
contracts on the future market shares of market participants. Where
by express contracts, the terms of such agreements are generally for more than th
are for an average of six years, with the result that hundreds of such agre
large venues (approximately 20 percent) expire each year.
170
Before the
contract. When Live Nation, for example, decided to seek an alternative t
it entertained a competitive bidding process and found many suitors with attractive
proposals before settling on vertical integration em
CTS.
171
AEG is now reportedly holding a similar bidding process in anti
expiration of its contract with T
169
Cf. Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, Raising Rivals Costs:
Anticompetitive Exclusion to Achieve Power over Price, 96 YALE L.J. 209, 267 (1986)
(“Certainly in most industries exclusionary rights contracts cannot be profitably
employed for anticompetitive ends.”).
170
See Ticketmaster Corp. v. Tickets.com, Inc., 2003-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶74,013, at
96,240-41 (C.D. Cal. 2003).
171
Michael Rapino Testimony, supra note 158, at 36-37.
168
Balto Testimony, supra note 151.
62
distributors both against each other and also against AEG’s alternative vertical
integ
172
everal bidding
al others with
of the Utah Jazz
and until now a Ticketmaster client. Ticketmaster loses many such contests to the
r’s exclusive
tribution business
s indicating that
er the next six
years. Because there are no apparent scale economies that would cause a large market
share to reduce the costs of ticket distribution, nor would any other externalities give
to believe that
Tic al bidders.
t is typical to ticket
et power.
nt, and as is discussed in detail in Part IV, infra, the
effects, and
antitrust scholars, enforcement officials, and courts have historically overestimated the
ration strategies.
Indeed, over the past three years, Ticketmaster has itself lost s
contests upon the expiration of contracts with large venues and sever
smaller venues. For instance, Veritix recently announced that it will take over all
ticketing operations for Salt Lake City’s EnergySolutions Arena, home
173
venue itself, which chooses to take on the task of distributing its own tickets instead of
renewing its distribution contract with Ticketmaster. Because Ticketmaste
agreements with venues expire on a regular basis, the nation’s ticket dis
is subject to a regular and ongoing competitive process, with some report
perhaps all such business will be available for bidding at some point ov
advantages to incumbents with large market shares, there is no reason
ketmaster has an undue advantage in that bidding process over riv
Consequently, there is little reason to conclude that the exclusivity tha
distribution agreements would enshrine or facilitate any meaningful mark
Perhaps more significa
exclusivity of such agreements often have procompetitive purposes and
172
Bloomberg.com, supra note 111.
173
See Veritix Signs Exclusive Ticketing Contract for Utah Jazz, EnergySolutions
Arena, TicketNews (Sept. 9, 2009), available at: http://www.ticketnews.com/Veritix-
signs-exclusive-ticketing-contract-for-Utah-Jazz-EnergySolutions-Arena9929188
63
prospect that such agreements would produce competitive harm. One reason that recent
tions, such as, for
venue.
benefits stemming
desirable
features such as “best seat available” searches and coordination of multiple marketing
s.
174
Any apparent “exclusionary” impact, then, is likely to be incidental to the
crea
oncentration and
y could deter and
defeat any efforts by incumbent firms to exercise market power. The entry analysis
would turn on many of the same industry-wide conditions and trends that have been
arely asked
s would enable
arket
participants section asked a similar question when determining whether venues that
icket distribution might become market participants in the face of
r’s unilateral effects
scholars and policymakers have applied less scrutiny to such vertical exclusive
arrangements is that they have easily recognizable efficiency explana
instance, encouraging investment in and financing of improvements to the
Moreover, a court expressly ruled on specific efficiencies and mutual
from exclusive agreements used by ticket distributors, which also enable
effort
tion of economic benefits.
Entry
Even if the proposed transaction were found to enhance market c
pose a plausible risk of anticompetitive harm, the prospect of new entr
175
central to our analysis to this point. Our market definition section squ
whether technology companies and other forms of technological progres
venues to self-distribute and thus become part of the relevant market. Our m
currently outsource t
supracompetitive prices. And our examination of the proposed merge
174
Ticketmaster Corp. v. Tickets.com, Inc., 2003-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 74,013, at
96,241 (C.D. Cal. 2003).
175
See United States v. Waste Mgmt., 743 F.2d 976 (2d Cir. 1984) (holding that prospect
of new entry rebutted government’s prima facie case that merger producing highly
concentrated market would result in anticompetitive effects).
64
inquires whether vertical integration and new technologies would counteract any effort
by a m
anies, promoters,
ge venues,
een noted above, there
s, that
technology companies are increasingly available to facilitate self-distribution, and that
176
to the
power.
177
ry has already
o as to realize
efficiencies resulting from the integration of the production, promotion, and ticketing of
live entertainment. Thus, such entry would certainly be “likely” if incumbent firms were
A review of entrants’ success suggest that the threat of additional entry is both
erational within two
arket leader to assert market power.
All of these sections turn on the ability of Internet software comp
and venues to spread the capacity to sell tickets for live performances at lar
either to venues themselves or to outsourced distributors. As has b
is substantial evidence that venues are pursuing self-distribution strategie
there are a growing number of competitive options to venues seeking to contract for
distribution services. The Horizontal Merger Guidelines focus attention
timeliness, the likelihood, and the sufficiency of entry to counteract market
Our sense is that the industry’s recent developments indicate that such ent
occurred and that venues will continue to adopt self-distribution strategies s
to attempt to exercise market power.
real and imminent. For example, Tessitura, a not-for-profit enterprise, entered the market
in the late 1990s by developing its own software de novo and was op
176
See supra notes 79-111 and accompanying text (listing numerous examples of venues
that have recently taken on the task of distributing their own tickets). See also
Ticketmaster Corp 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,241 (explaining that the option of self-
distribution via reliance on outside technology providers prevents Ticketmaster from
exercising market power).
177
See 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines § 3.0. See also Cardinal Health, 12 F. Supp. 2d at
54-58 (applying this taxonomy to evaluate defendants’ claim that prospect of new entry
should rebut plaintiff’s prima facie case).
65
to three years. Given technological developments since then, including the rapid
entry could
that Live
it decided to do
ss could not
ues, including the Los
Angeles Staples Center, Miami’s American Airlines Arena, the Target Center in
ong others.
180
The
tHorse, to manage a
tion
arrangements (indeed, the firm had earlier suggested that it might take its business
elsewhere if the Live Nation/Ticketmaster merger is approved).
183
If, contrary to our
AEG and other
ers are likely to create their own ticketing technologies or license
178
diffusion of Internet ticketing technology, we would expect that de novo
occur much more quickly today. Indeed, opponents of the transaction claim
Nation entered the ticket distribution market just a few short months after
so, and there is no reason that other participants in the entertainment busine
do the same.
179
AEG, for instance, owns or manages dozens of ven
Minneapolis, Charlotte’s Time Warner Cable Arena, Portland, Oregon’s Rose Quarter,
Kansas City’s Sprint Center, and San Antonio’s AT&T Arena, am
firm recently partnered with Kroenke Sports, the owner of Ticke
venue in Colorado. Currently AEG outsources the distribution at most of its venues to
Ticketmaster,
181
but it reportedly is preparing to seek alternative distribu
182
expectations, the merger were to result in an exercise of market power,
adjacent market play
178
.tessituranetwork.com/en/About/Timeline.aspx (repo See http://www rting that the
t was
ng numerous venues
ed Aug. 10, 2009).
181
The Portland Rose Garden, however, self distributes with Paciolan technology.
182
See supra, note 111.
183
See Ticketmaster Client May End Contract if Merger OKed, REUTERS, Feb. 26, 2009,
available at http://www.reuters.com/article/innovationNewsConsumerGoodsAndRetail/
idUSTRE51P7W820090226 (reporting AEG letter advising Ticketmaster that approval of
Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger would release AEG from its ticket distribution
agreement with Ticketmaster).
New York Metropolitan Opera authorized entry in 1996 and that the projec
completed in 1998-1999).
179
Balto Testimony, supra note 151, at 2.
180
See http://www.aegworldwide.com/01_venues/venues.php (listi
owned by AEG) (last visit
66
such technology from others and entering the distribution market (and they may do so
uld, all by
have the same
s be “sufficient” to counteract any purported antitcompetitive effects from
Nor is AEG the only likely entrant. At least one major record label—Warner
arket, using
186
follow in the
nnounced that it
ster client, along
wsletter
opined that the spin off, creating a new entity worth $1.5 billion, would “instantly
ed entertainment partners Ticketmaster and
g.
even if the merged Live Nation Entertainment does not exercise market power). One
critic of the proposed transaction has argued that entry by Live Nation wo
itself, lower ticket prices.
184
If so, then presumably entry by AEG would
effect and thu
the transaction.
185
Music Group—has predicted that it will soon enter the ticket distribution m
its relationships with artists as a segue. Other major promoters could
steps of AEG and Live Nation. Indeed, in August 2009, Cablevision a
would be spinning off Madison Square Garden, currently a Ticketma
with Radio City Music Hall and other assets. The leading ticket industry ne
creat[e] a possible future competitor to propos
Live Nation.”
187
Presumably such rivalry would include rivalry in ticketin
184
Balto Testimony, supra note 151, at 3.
185
Cf. Cardinal Health, 12 F. Supp. 2d at 58 (finding that entry, while time
would not be “sufficient” to counter-act hypothesized output reduction in th
market).
186
See Transcript of Warner Music Group Call, Addressing Fourth Quart
Earnings (
ly and likely,
e relevant
er 2008
February 9, 2009) (recounting the steps that the firm is taking to “broaden its
sorship, fanclub,
, touring, ticketing and artist management.”); id. (stating that the
firm has been involved in “fan club management” since 2004, including “VIP ticketing”);
id. (stating that, going forward “physical recorded music business will continue to be a
smaller and smaller part of our business . . . . we’ll also be significantly in the business of
sharing the revenues with artists, ticketing, touring, artist management, sponsorship, fan
clubs, etc.”).
187
See http://www.ticketnews.com/Ticket-News-Announces-Top-Ticket-Sellers-for-
Week-Ending-August-1-2009.
revenue mix in the growing areas of the music business, including spon
Websites, merchandising
67
It is difficult to credit the claim made by some that exclusive contracts entered by
er.
188
With the
ll-service
Ticketmaster. For
ts can
actually facilitate this category of entry by providing upstart firms with the assurance that
189
ted entry to
technologies
w, have found
ution, and it might
be said that these enabling firms represent two different kinds of entry: entry by venues
into self-distribution, and entry by technology firms that enable self-distribution.
firms has the potential to
Ticketmaster, Tickets.com, and other providers of distribution services prevent the sort of
entry that would be necessary to counteract any exercise of market pow
spread of ticketing technologies, there remains the potential for entry by fu
outsourced ticket distributors with the business model popularized by
firms aiming to enter the market with this business model, exclusive contrac
any sunk investments will pay off before a customer switches to a different supplier.
More significantly, recent technological developments have permit
take place through alternative mechanisms. Firms that market “enabling”
that facilitate self-distribution strategies, such as Veritix and AudienceVie
a growing demand among venues to pursue cost-effective self-distrib
Accordingly, the emergence of even a small number of enabling
188
The Department of Justice in the 1990s investigated allegations of illeg
monopolization, which charged that Ticketmaster’s exclusive contracts res
and caused anticompetitive harm. The Antitrust Division ultimately decl
these claims. See U.S. Ends
al
tricted entry
ined to pursue
Ticketmaster Investigation, N.Y. T
IMES, July 6, 1995, at
concluded that
s are procompetitive and that there are no barriers to
entering the ticket distribution business. See Balto Testimony, supra note 151, at 1-2.
See also Ticketmaster Corp v. Tickets.com, Inc., 2003-1 Trade Cas.(CCH) ¶ 74,013 (C.D.
Cal. 2003) (granting summary judgment against claim of attempted monopolization on
similar and other bases). In Part IV we offer a complete assessment of the competitive
consequences of such agreements.
189
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 3.3 (explaining that “forward contracting” can help
new entrants divest sales from incumbents).
C14. One opponent of this transaction has reported that the Department
Ticketmaster’s contracts with venue
68
significantly shape the economic impact of new sources of output.
190
Should
entrants. At the
ers entrants to counter
tive prices.
Con n
Some critics argue that, regardless of the transaction’s impact (or lack thereof) on
current revent
arate entities. That is,
on was poised
cket
affiliation. By merging with Live Nation, these critics claim, Ticketmaster would thwart
Live Nation’s impending substantial and procompetitive expansion in a market segment
whe he merger
ght exist
ctices that
reduce competition that never in fact existed. Still, it is perhaps possible to accommodate
instance, just
as a firm’s apparent market share might overstate its actual competitive significance, so
too might its apparent market presence understate its competitive influence, influence
Ticketmaster or any market participant raise prices, we would expect acceleration in the
trend toward self-distribution and perhaps the addition of new species of
very least, it appears that currently available technology empow
any SSNIP by Ticketmaster with comparable services at competi
cerns About a Purported Loss of “Future” or “Potential” Competitio
the firms’ rivalry, combining Live Nation and Ticketmaster will p
competition that would have occurred had the parties remained sep
these critics claim that, before the announcement of this merger, Live Nati
to become a particularly effective rival in the non-captive segment of the ti
distribution market, distributing millions of tickets for venues with whom it had no prior
re it now barely participates. More colloquially, it might be said, t
eliminates “potential competition” in addition to whatever actual rivalry mi
between Ticketmaster and Live Nation.
The antitrust laws do not by their terms prevent transactions or pra
this sort of concern within the existing framework of merger doctrine. For
190
See Joint Merger Guidelines, § 3.3 (likelihood of new entry depends upon availability
of sales and the minimum viable scale of production).
69
that a proposed transaction could eliminate. That competitive influence could be
ether poses a
ercises of
uld be nascent
rediction that a competitive challenge would have
occ
At the same time, any potential competition claim should not serve as a vehicle
erger
late the
antitrust laws. The antitrust laws do not smash the economy into individual atoms and
require courts to undo productive cooperation to ensure the maximum amount of putative
191
tangible, such as when a recent entrant or a firm outside the market altog
credible threat of sudden output increases or new entry and thus deters ex
market power by established market participants.
192
Or the influence co
and potential, resting merely on a p
urred absent the transaction.
193
for circumventing and avoiding the rigorous principles that ordinarily guide m
analysis. Every merger that eliminates a “nascent competitor” does not vio
191
Cf. Gen. Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 498-99, 503-10 (concluding that ma
concentration statistics significantly overstated competitive impact of me
192
See United States v. Falstaff Brewing Corp., 410 U.S. 526, 533-37 (19
this theory to remand decision for reconsideration by lower court); id. at 5
concurring in the judgment) (“From the perspective of the firms al
the possibility of entry by such a lingering firm may be an important consid
their pricing and marketing decisions. When the lingering firm enters
acquisition, the competitive influence exerted by the firm is lost with no off
through an increase in the number of companies seeking a share of the
The result is a net decrease in competitive pressure.”) (citation omitted)
rket
rger).
73) (relying on
59 (Marshall, J.
ready in the market,
eration in
the market by
setting gain
relevant market.
; Department of
rger
ed on theory that
sponse to
tions by other market participants); Joint Merger Guidelines,
§ 4.111 (“By eliminating a significant present competitive threat that constrains the
behavior of the firms already in the market, the merger could result in an immediate
deterioration in market performance.”).
193
Cf. Tenneco Inc. v. FTC, 689 F.2d 346, 355-58 (2d Cir. 1982) (articulating standards
governing application of actual potential competition doctrine); FTC v. Atl. Richfield
Co., 549 F. 2d 289 (4th Cir. 1977) (same); 1984 Department of Justice Non-Horizontal
Merger Guidelines, § 4.112 (same).
Justice and Federal Trade Commission Commentary on the Horizontal Me
Guidelines, 24-25 (March 2006) (discussing enforcement actions premis
acquired firm was a “maverick” capable of rapidly expanding output in re
anticompetitive output reduc
70
rivalry that is possible. Moreover, as Yogi Berra put it, “prediction is very hard,
idly evolving marketplace would have
unf
iction that it
would eliminate meaningful competition that has not yet occurred can deprive the public
194
especially about the future,” and government agencies and courts have no special wisdom
allowing them to forecast how a dynamic and rap
olded but for a voluntary transaction under review.
195
Banning otherwise beneficial integration based on an incorrect pred
194
See White Consol. Indus., Inc. v. Whirlpool Corp., 781 F.2d 1224, 12
1986) (“[I]t is not this Court’s duty to permit only the most competiti
imaginable. This Court may only block proposed transactions the effect o
to substantially lessen competition.”); United States v. AMAX, Inc., 402 F.
959 (D. Conn. 1975) (mere fact that parties could achieve their objectives
restrictive means does not require condemnation of merger that does not
substantially lessen competition). See also Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dis
466 U.S. 2, 44, n.13 (1984) (O’Connor, J. concurring) (purported les
achieving agreement’s objective only relevant for rule of reason purposes i
agreement produces harm in the first place); Broad. Music, Inc. v. CBS, 44
(1979) (mere fact that agreement or merger eliminates competition does no
render it inherently suspect); Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 221 U.S.
(1911) (ban on any arrangement that reduces rivalry would “render difficu
33 (6thCir.
ve agreement
f which may be
Supp. 956,
via less
otherwise
t. No. 2 v. Hyde,
s restrictive means of
f the
1 U.S. 1, 23
t thereby
106, 180
lt if not
); N. Sec. Co.
that majority
opinion would
far as it could
t Sherman Act
etition).
rity on mergers
rocter and Gamble
rocter and Gamble
cter & Gamble Co., 386
U.S. 568, 580-81 (1967) (sustaining FTC’s determination that Procter and Gamble was
the “most likely entrant” into the household bleach market). Four decades later, Procter
still does not participate in the household bleach market. Luke Froeb, Testimony Before
the House Committee on Courts and Competition, 6 n. 4 (2009). See also e.g. John E.
Lopatka, United States v. IBM: A Monument to Arrogance, 68 A
NTITRUST L.J. 145
(2000) (collecting numerous predictions by antitrust scholars and lawyers that IBM
would perpetually retain unassailable monopoly over personal computers).
impossible any movement of trade in the channels of interstate commerce”
v. United States, 193 U.S. 197, 411 (1904) (Holmes, J. dissenting) (noting
of the Court had rejected “an interpretation of the law which in [Holmes’]
make eternal the bellum omnium contra omnes and disintegrate society so
into individual atoms”); id. at 361-64 (Brewer, J. concurring) (opining tha
only banned combinations that resulted in unreasonable reductions in comp
195
For instance, recent testimony about this transaction by a noted autho
recalled that, more than forty years ago, the Supreme Court ordered P
to divest Clorox at the behest of the United States on the theory that P
would then enter the household bleach market. See FTC v. Pro
71
of beneficial integration and deter future beneficial transactions as well.
6
Indeed, this
ergers
197
salient here,
vertical aspects of
saction will create efficiencies that society would forgo if the transaction is
scu
Even if we assume that a potential competition doctrine applies here, we do not
ore
al effects
ready assesses the
suggest that its
eory of
potential competition suggests that Live Nation is likely to expand in its non-captive
d. But even if
19
concern may well explain why courts are so reluctant to sustain challenges to m
based upon a “potential competition” theory. This concern is particularly
where the trend toward vertical integration raises the inference that the
this tran
ttled.
198
believe that Live Nation’s future influence on the marketplace changes the m
conventional analysis of this transaction. One reason is that our horizont
analysis—evaluating actual, as opposed to potential, competition—al
possibility of Live Nation possessing captive production, which would
market share overstates its competitive significance. A claim based on a th
ticket distribution capabilities. No such specific plans have been announce
196
Cf. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Commenta
Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 1 (March 2006) (“Mergers between com
‘horizontal’ mergers, are a significant dynamic force in the American econo
majority of merger
ry on the
peting firms, i.e.,
my. The vast
ces, or
ompete more
ustice and Federal
mission Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 0.1 (“the agency seeks to avoid
ither competitively
197
See infra notes 210-212 (collecting numerous authorities in which courts rejected
such challenges). See also Donald F. Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section 7 of the
Clayton Act, 78 HARV.L.REV. 1313, 1317-18 (1965) (describing various benefits of
mergers the existence of which counsels against overbroad rules prohibiting such
transactions).
198
Specific efficiencies related to the vertical integration of Ticketmaster and Live
Nation are discussed infra Part IV.3.
s pose no harm to consumers, and many produce efficiencies that
benefit consumers in the form of lower prices, higher quality goods or servi
investments in innovation. Efficiencies such as these enable companies to c
effectively, both domestically and overseas.”); 1992 Department of J
Trade Com
unnecessary interference with the larger universe of mergers that are e
beneficial or neutral.”).
72
Live Nation had such a credible plan, any showing that Live Nation would have
aster
d thus is
susceptible to procompetitive influence.
199
However, our evaluation of the ticket
exercised procompetitive influence on the market but for its merger with Ticketm
requires a threshold showing that the market is less than competitive an
199
Thus, by analogy, courts and the enforcement agencies have repea
a “perceived potential entrant” and an “actual potential entrant” cannot
procompetitive influence on the marketplace unless concentration and othe
establish that the market is otherwise susceptible to coordinated or u
anticompetitive behavior.
tedly held that both
exercise a
r indicia
nilateral
ly because Live
Nat itself made it plain
that e market in
que
as meaning
e comes into
rget market
he capacity
ices. If
ust
spects of
genuinely
). Accord e.g.
was not
ctrine). See also
(“As Professor
able to the
competitive to
nfluenced by
nt
7 of the
ol. Foods
f the perceived
vior” and
polistic practices”)
(alternate holding); United States v. Hughes Tool Co., 415 F. Supp. 637, 645 (C.D. Cal.
1976) (rejecting application of perceived potential competition doctrine because “the
relevant market here is not highly concentrated and is freely competitive”); In re B.A.T.,
104 F.T.C. at 923, n.22 (collecting authorities for the proposition that the doctrine does
not apply where nominally high concentration statistics present a misleading picture of
competition in the relevant market); 1984 Department of Justice Non-Horizontal Merger
Guidelines, § 4.111 (application of perceived potential competition doctrine depends
There is no reason to reject this logic simp
ion is already present in the marketplace. The Supreme Court has
there can be no concern about a loss of potential competition if th
stion is already competitive.
The [actual and perceived] potential-competition doctrine h
only as applied to concentrated markets. That is, the doctrin
play only where there are dominant participants in the ta
engaging in interdependent or parallel behavior and with t
effectively to determine price and total output of goods and serv
the target market performs as a competitive market in traditional antitr
terms . . . . there would be no need for concern about the pro
long-term deconcentration of a market which is in fact
competitive.
See United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602,630 (1974
Tenneco, 689 F. 2d at 352-53 (sustaining Commission finding that “market
genuinely competitive,” a necessary element for application of the do
United States v. Siemens Corp., 621 F.2d 499, 505 n.6 (2d Cir. 1980)
Turner points out the perceived potential competition doctrine is only avail
Government if the market is oligopolistic. If the market is sufficiently
enforce competitive behavior on existing sellers, their behavior will not be i
the threat of new entry, thus making the loss of a perceived potential entra
insignificant.”) (citing Donald Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section
Clayton Act, 78 H
ARV.L.REV. 1313, 1363 (1965)); United States v. Cons
Corp., 455 F. Supp. 108, 139-140 (E.D. Pa. 1978) (rejecting application o
potential entry doctrine where there was “no evidence of oligopolistic beha
levels of profitability were “indicative of competitive, rather than oligo
73
distribution market suggests that it is an increasingly dynamic and competitive market,
em that the
is initial
mpower courts to thwart a
mer t.
201
Moreover, there is no reason to believe that Live Nation—as opposed to any
utsourced
hat is to say,
e in this segment but
for the merger, there are other firms that are well suited to enter the market or rapidly
expand their presence within it. If this is the case, then eliminating Live Nation’s
such that Ticketmaster’s current significant market share, even when included with Live
Nation’s output, is unlikely to translate into market power. It would se
potential competition claim would have significant difficulty overcoming th
requirement and would thus fail.
200
The antitrust laws do not e
ger merely to add yet another rival to an already competitive marke
number of other firms that could enter the distribution market or expand their presence in
it—is uniquely well-suited to be the source of potential competition in the o
ticket distribution segment and thereby deter anticompetitive conduct. T
even assuming Live Nation would have rapidly expanded its presenc
l competition
firms” to “restrain their pricing in order
application of
e
ive potential
cision above,
ministration and
rity on antitrust doctrine and policy.
ine,
otherwise it would swallow the whole of merger law. See AMAX, Inc., 402 F. Supp. at
959 (noting that the argument that internal expansion would be more competitive than a
merger could be made “against any horizontal merger” and thus does not justify
preventing such a transaction). See also BMI, 441 U.S. at 23 (explaining that numerous
mergers between competitors and other competition-reducing transactions properly
withstand antitrust scrutiny).
201
See White Consol. Indus., Inc., 781 F.2d at 1233; AMAX, Inc, 402 F. Supp. at 959.
upon the “economic theory of limit pricing” and assumption that potentia
encourages “monopolists and groups of colluding
to deter new entry”). See also Tenneco Inc., 689 F.2d at 355-58 (rejecting
the “perceived potential competition” doctrine where market had recently becom
significantly competitive independent of any influence exercised by putat
entrant). It should be noted that Professor Turner, cited in the Siemens de
served as head of the Antitrust Division during President Johnson’s ad
was a preeminent autho
200
Moreover, there need to be meaningful limits on any potential competition doctr
74
competitive influence cannot produce anticompetitive harm and cannot serve as a basis
for disallowing the m
202
s will, in fact, enter
ndidates
EG, the world’s
n) and the
world’s largest owner of sporting teams and events. If Live Nation, having entered the
only for its
ing its reported
is Veritix.
tinue expanding its
client base, both independently and via its downstream relationship with Kroenke Sports
aster and
erger.
As admirers of Yogi Berra, we hesitate to predict which firm
the market or expand their presence within it. Nonetheless, two prime ca
emerged in the previous section discussing market entry. The first is A
second largest promoter of live music and entertainment (after Live Natio
market just a few months ago after obtaining technology from a third party, is poised
rapidly to expand its presence in a segment in which it now participates
internal business needs, then presumably AEG could do the same by pursu
plans to acquire self-distribution technology.
203
A second likely candidate
Given the trend toward ticket self-distribution, Veritix is likely to con
and its TicketHorse subsidiary, particularly as contracts between Ticketm
202
See Atl. Richfield Co., 549 F.2d at 300 (declining to ban merger that p
reduced potential competition because there were several other possible e
Hughes Tool, 415 F. Supp. at 646 (same). See also In re B.A.T. Indus.
852, 924 (1984) (“[E]liminating one of many potential entrants could not
eliminate substantial future competition.”). Here again one finds a re
“perceived potential competition doctrine,” the application of which require
that the alleged potential entrant is one of very few likely entrants s
of the entrant would in fact eliminate or substantially reduce the overall th
into the relevant market.
urportedly
ntrants);
Ltd., 104 F.T.C.
be expected to
ady analogy in the
s a showing
uch that elimination
reat of entry
See Siemens, 621 F.2d at 509 (rejecting application of the
l entry doctrine where there were various other potential entrants into
the market in question); United States v. Black & Decker Mfg. Co., 430 F. Supp.
729,771-773 (D. Md. 1976) (same); Frank H. Easterbrook, Comment, Toehold
Acquisitions and the Potential Competition Doctrine, 40 U. C
HI.L.REV. 156, 169 (1972)
(“If there are many potential competitors, the removal of one of them cannot be
important, because the continued presence of the remaining firms will discipline the
market to the same extent.”).
203
See suora, note 111.
perceived potentia
75
various venues expire. Any claim that an independent Live Nation, and not AEG or
ake sizeable market inroads over the next few years rests on additional
spe
hich by its nature
tate of
ing the Supreme Court,
have repeatedly ruled out the imposition of liability based upon “uncabined
206 207 208
Instead, as the
mergers
rts have placed
particular emphasis on these considerations when assessing claims that mergers eliminate
lied on these
204
Veritix, will m
culation.
Some speculation is an inevitable part of merger analysis, w
requires courts and enforcement agencies to make predictions about the s
competition after the transaction.
205
Nonetheless, courts, includ
speculation” “ephemeral possibilities,” or “remote possibilities.”
Supreme Court said more than four decades ago, Section 7 bans only those
where the anticompetitive effect is “probable.”
209
Not surprisingly, cou
competition that has not yet occurred.
210
Indeed, at least one court has re
204
See supra note 170 and accompanying text (explaining that most distrib
agreements between Ticketmaster and various venues wi
ution
next three to
stream
Act is with
1045, 1051
ies are not
. Falstaff, 410 U.S.
g)).
g with ephemeral
to be proscribed by
this Act”); id. at n. 39 (citing legislative history to this effect); Tenet Health, 186 F.3d at
1051 (Clayton Act “deals in probabilities, not ephemeral possibilities”). See also
Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines, §
0.1 (“Throughout the Guidelines, the analysis is focused on whether consumers or
producers ‘likely would’ take certain actions.”).
210
See Tenneco, 689 F.2d at 354 (rejecting government’s invocation of the actual
potential competition doctrine for reliance upon “speculation” and “ephemeral
ll expire over the
six years). Cf. 1992 Joint Merger Guidelines § 3.3 (providing that down
integration can facilitate entry into a new market).
205
See Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323 (concern of Section 7 of the Clayton
“probabilities, not certainties”).
206
See British Oxygen Co. v. FTC, 557 F.2d 24, 29 (2d Cir. 1977).
207
See Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323; FTC v. Tenet Health Care, 186 F.3d
(8th Cir. 1999); British Oxygen, 557 F.2d at 28.
208
See Marine Bancorp., Inc., 418 U.S. 623, n. 22 (“[R]emote possibilit
sufficient to satisfy the test set forth in § 7.”) (quoting United States v
526, 555 (1972) (Marshall, J. concurrin
209
Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323 (“[N]o statute was sought for dealin
possibilities. Mergers with a probable anticompetitive effect were
76
admonitions when rejecting the claim—like that made here—that a merging party’s
re-merger
211
n the
etition” require a showing that future entry by one
of t
irreplaceably
influential competitor but for this merger rests on the sort of unjustified speculation that
segment, the
ct of other entrants,
on Live Nation,
petitive
le ge to Ticketmaster seems to lack the factual grounding in objective reality that
courts have repeatedly required (and often found wanting) when evaluating analogous
market share understated its competitive significance because it had p
expansion plans. Some courts have even suggested that claims based o
elimination of “actual potential comp
he merging firms was “almost certain.”
212
The claim that Live Nation would have become a particularly and
courts have rejected. Given Live Nation’s very limited track record in this
established records and capabilities of other participants, the prospe
and the lack of apparent structural features conferring unique advantages
any prediction that Live Nation would pose a unique and substantial com
chal n
claims.
213
nt’s reliance upon
t”).
n pre-merger
e such an
an the
ility and
iring “clear
of the Clayton
f that the firm
would in fact have entered” such that preventing merger will lead to future entry “[g]iven
the less than overwhelming case for prohibition to begin with”); id. at 1386 (advocating
requirement that such future entry was “certain”).
213
See Tenneco, 689 F.2d at 354; British Oxygen, 557 F.2d at 28-30; Atl. Richfield Co.,
549 F.2d at 300 (declining to ban merger that purportedly reduced potential competition
because there were several other possible entrants as well); Hughes Tool, 415 F. Supp. at
646 (same). See also Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section 7 of the Clayton Act,
possibilities”); British Oxygen, 557 F.2d at 28-30 (rejecting governme
“uncabined speculation” and “wholly speculative . . . 'eventual entry' tes
211
See AMAX, Inc., 402 F. Supp. at 960 (rejecting government’s reliance o
expansion plans to inflate merging parties’ competitive significance becaus
approach would “ask that this court adopt ‘ephemeral possibilities’ rather th
‘probability’ which § 7 requires”) (citations omitted).
212
See Siemens, 621 F. 2d at 506 (requiring “at least” a reasonable probab
“preferably clear proof”); Atl. Richfield Co., 549 F.2d at 294-95, 300 (requ
proof”). See also Donald F. Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section 7
Act, 78 H
ARV.L.REV. 1313, 1384 (arguing for requirement of “clear proo
77
Horizontal Efficiencies Resulting from the Merger
any
f the merger,
ments would yield
he consolidation of their
tick le.
Like most information technology services, there are probably some scale
re interesting
ketmaster, the
de services of
operate on its
own. Certainly, it is possible that Ticketmaster, a historically successful distributor, has
certain capabilities that Live Nation, a relative a newcomer to ticket distribution, does
not.
214
that Internet
widespread and
commoditized, then any one company’s technological advantage would be limited.
echnology
re likely to have capabilities that other companies cannot duplicate, even
Although Live Nation and Ticketmaster claim that their merger will create m
efficiencies, these efficiencies will likely result from the vertical elements o
discussed in Part IV, infra. It is less certain whether the horizontal ele
any substantial efficiencies that are directly attributable to t
eting distribution services, but some efficiencies might be possib
economies in ticket distribution. If scale efficiencies are nontrivial, then consolidation
would avoid duplicative investments and could yield some savings. A mo
possibility for horizontal efficiencies is that the merger would enable Tic
accomplished technology company, to handle ticket distribution and provi
higher quality and at lower costs than what Live Nation could build and
However, this argument is in tension with the growing evidence
technologies are easy to acquire. If the underlying technology really is
We suspect the truth lies somewhere in the middle. Accomplished t
companies a
78 HARV.L.REV. at 1382 (“Unless a firm possesses unique capabilities, its preparation to
enter a market by internal expansion suggests that the market presents attractive
opportunities that at least one other firm will be likely to seek, also by internal expansion
if necessary.”).
214
Because Ticketmaster is the recognized industry leader and purportedly enjoys these
efficiencies already, these particular efficiencies would be “merger specific.” Live
Nation could not realize them by, say, merging with a different entity.
78
when the market’s technological demands are not great, and this suggests that ticket
erger than
rse venues,
veal that the venues’
r costs they
e technologies
themselves. Accordingly, if any horizontal efficiencies are possible, they either are
modest or they are easily swa
erger with the
phistication,
Service providers also range from full-service ticket distributors to providers
ough we lack
ity tests for market
wide variation in services offered and that
ion. .
self-distribute their
asingly
shares,
ppears to be
rket
share, but most
ively
significant.
4. Even under narrow market definitions in which Ticketmaster and Live Nation
enjoy large market shares, the ease and attractiveness of vertical integration as
well as the nature of rivalry within the ticketing market prevents Ticketmaster,
or any other ticket distributor, from exercising market power and charging
supracompetitive prices. This critical determination hinges on precisely how
distribution for Live Nation events would occur more efficiently with the m
without it. However, the proliferation of self-distribution strategies by dive
most of which do not have track records as technology companies, re
vertical integration strategies generate efficiencies that exceed whateve
encounter (and otherwise could save from outsourcing) by pursuing th
mped by the efficiencies from vertical integration.
Summary
We close this analysis of the horizontal elements of the proposed m
following preliminary conclusions:
1. Venues that purchase ticket distribution services vary in size, so
and needs, and service providers accordingly present a menu of offerings.
of technology that enables self-distribution. Subsequently, alth
sufficient information to conduct the required cross-elastic
definition, we observe that there is
defining a distinct product market is a difficult determinat
2. The technology required for large and smaller venues to
tickets is becoming increasingly available, and venues are incre
vertically integrating into ticket distribution.
3. Under most characterizations of market participants and market
Ticketmaster enjoys a large market share, such that the market a
moderately or highly concentrated. Live Nation, under some ma
characterizations, has a much smaller but still sizable market
or all of its output is captive and thus is unlikely to be competit
79
easy and attractive vertical integration is for large venues. M
venues appear to solicit bids from multiple providers, there
focused
oreover, because
are moments of
competition that dull any advantage of incumbency or historical
ketmaster and
utors is unlikely to produce anticompetitive harm
cognizable under the antirust laws because the market is apparently behaving
6. Any horizontal efficiencies produced by this merger appear to be modest.
market share.
5. The elimination of Live Nation as a potential competitor to Tic
other ticket distrib
in a competitive manner.
IV. Analysis of Merger’s Vertical Consequences
Although the proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger has some
horizontal elements, the companies’ core businesses lie in differen
Accordingly, the transaction is more accurately described as a primarily ve
resulting in the integration of successive stages of the process of producing
over the past three decades, the antitrust enforcement agencies have chall
handful of the thousands of vertical mergers that have occurred in the
very few p
important
t market segments.
rtical merger,
and
delivering entertainment to the consumer. There is a broad consensus among economists
and legal scholars that vertical mergers only very rarely pose competitive risks. Indeed,
enged only a
United States, and
rivate challenges during this period have been successful.
215
Such consistency
among scholars, policymakers, and courts reveal a recognition that vertical mergers are
or protect motivated primarily by efficiency concerns, rather than efforts to acquire
market power.
215
See, e.g, Alberta Gas Chems. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours, 826 F.2d 1235, 1244-46
(3d Cir. 1987) (summarizing law governing vertical mergers); Fruehauf Corp. v. FTC,
603 F.2d 345, 351-359 (2d Cir. 1979) (rejecting challenge to vertical merger); Crouse-
Hinds Co. v. Internorth, Inc., 518 F. Supp. 416, 428-34 (same); Crane Co. v. Harsco
Corp., 509 F. Supp. 115, 125-26 (D. Del. 1981) (same).
80
Nonetheless, some critics of the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger claim that
us
merger, we
ubstantial
hat have convinced Live
o the
procompetitive motivations that underlie the use of exclusive contracts between ticket
ting those
master merger
but not limited
iew the major
ects of the transaction will produce anticompetitive harm, and
we find them to rest on speculative predictions of harm that are generally implausible in
light of the industry’s structure.
coordination, by
rocess, where
n, all business
firms are “vertically integrated,” in the sense that they perform tasks by two or more
actors who might otherwise operate as independent market actors and cooperate together
by contract. Even the child’s corner lemonade stand can exemplify such integration–if
the child produces the lemonade (instead of buying lemonade on the market) and then
distributes it at retail. Nobel Laureate Ronald Coase first famously observed that markets
vertical integration between these two particular firms will produce vario
anticompetitive consequences. In reviewing the vertical aspects of this
identify many reasons to believe that the merger will more likely result in s
transactional efficiencies. Indeed, the efficiency considerations t
Nation and Ticketmaster to now seek vertical integration are analogous t
distributors, as the Department of Justice apparently concluded after investiga
practices during the 1990s. Furthermore, the proposed Live Nation-Ticket
reflects the industry’s general trend towards vertical integration, including
to the integration of venue ownership and ticket distribution. We lastly rev
arguments that vertical asp
The Evolving Economic and Legal Treatment of Vertical Integration
Broadly conceived, “vertical integration” entails any conscious
contract or ownership, of two or more successive stages of the production p
“production” can include the provision of services or goods. By definitio
81
and firms are merely alternative mechanisms to organize economic activity,
216
and this
ics. When
economic
h, remarked
ition in a ‘market’
for a far more complicated continuum,”
218
they were
repeating Coase’s prescient insight.
olars
integration
taking control of a
h integration could
s for
distributing their products, thereby creating a “clog on competition” to the ultimate
detriment of downstream consumers.
219
A classic example was the merger between the
Brown Shoe Company—a shoe manufacturer—and Kinney Shoe Co., which
analytical lens has deeply penetrated the fields of both law and econom
Richard Posner stated that “[v]ertical integration is a universal feature of
life,”
217
and Frank Easterbrook, shortly before his appointment to the benc
that “[t]he dichotomy between cooperation inside a ‘firm’ and compet
is just a convenient shorthand
Still, several decades ago, courts, the enforcement agencies, and legal sch
were quite hostile to vertical integration, despite its ubiquity, whether such
occurred by merger, internal expansion, or long-term contract. By
new stage of the process of production or distribution, it was said, suc
“foreclose” rivals from particular upstream inputs or downstream channel
216
See Coase, supra note 121, at 389 (“It can, I think, be assumed that the distinguishing
mark of the firm is the supersession of the price m hanism.”). ec
217
See generally Jack Walters & Sons v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d
1984) (Posner, J.) (“Vertical integration is a universal feature of economic life . . . . A
common type of vertical integration is for a manufacturer
698 (7th Cir.
to take over the distribution of
his own product.”); id. at 698.
218
Frank Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX.L.REV. 1, 1 (1984). To be fair,
this remark (like Bork’s, supra note 230) embraces an approach that began with Ronald
Coase’s seminal article, The Nature of the Firm, supra note 121, and predated TCE.
219
See Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 324 (invoking these metaphors when condemning a
vertical merger); Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 314 (1940) (invoking
these metaphors when condemning exclusive dealing agreements).
82
manufactured shoes and also owned four hundred shoe stores throughout the country.
220
ably “force”
als from access to
various
courts and the
e
“inhospitality tradition,” in which vertical arrangements, including vertical mergers, were
s.
222
Although judicial and administrative hostility, or inhospitality, to vertical
the time,
223
After purchasing Kinney, the government argued, Brown would presum
Kinney stores to stock Brown Shoes, thereby foreclosing its riv
Kinney’s stores, which had, before the merger, stocked shoes from
manufacturers.
221
This approach dominated antitrust analysis by
enforcement agencies, giving rise to what subsequently became known as th
suspected to have monopoly motivations and anticompetitive consequence
integration might have made sense given the state of economic science at
220
See Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 302-304 (reporting that Kinney owned 40
which sold about 1.6 percent of the nation’s shoes).
221
See id. at 304 (finding that, after the merger, Brown supplied 7.9 perc
sold at Kinney stores); id. at 334 (banning merger because of “trend towar
integration in the shoe industry, when combined with Brown’s avowed po
its own shoes upon its retail subsidiaries, may foreclose competition from a substantial
share of the markets for men’s, women’s and children’s shoes, without prod
countervailing competitive, economic or social advantages.”). See also F
Shoe Co., 384 U.S. 31
0 shoe stores
ent of the shoes
d vertical
licy of forcing
ucing any
TC v. Brown
6, 320-21 (1966) (finding that a quasi-exclusive dealing agreement
of the Sherman
ction 5 of the FTC
the policy of
in the open
f prohibited
ision, was
ons not
of antitrust law.”
Alan J. Meese, Raising Rivals’ Costs: Can the Agencies Do More Good Than Harm?, 12
G
EO.MASON L. REV. 241, 260 (2003). n.98 (quoting Donald F. Turner, Some Reflections
on Antitrust, 1966 N.Y. St. B.A. Antitrust L. Symp. 1, 1–2 (1966)).
223
See JOE S. BAIN,INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, 381 (1959) (“The trained observer
tends to form a considerable suspicion from casual observation that there is a good deal
of vertical integration which, although not actually uneconomical, is also not justified on
the basis of any cost savings. This is apparently true in particular of the integration of
involving 1% of the nation’s shoe retailers offended the “central policy
Act” and thus constituted an “unfair trade practice” in violation of Se
Act); Dictograph Prod, Inc. v. FTC, 217 F.2d 821, 828 (2d Cir. 1954) (“It is
the Congress that [the defendant’s] merchandise must stand on its own feet
market . . . without the competitive advantage to be obtained by the use o
exclusionary agreements.”).
222
Donald Turner, then head of the Department of Justice’s Antitrust Div
famously quoted to have said, “I approach territorial and customer restricti
hospitably in the common law tradition, but inhospitably in the tradition
83
economic theory has advanced significantly since the 1950s and views the causes and
inent
fession has
m and other
onomists and
t rvice) is best
understood as an effort to economize on what Coase dubbed “transaction costs.”
225
By
ight
consequences of vertical integration much more sympathetically. In what one prom
economist has properly characterized as a scientific revolution, the pro
completely reconceptualized the theoretical rationale for the business fir
forms of vertical integration.
224
Building on Coase’s original insight, ec
others have recognized that vertical integration (“making” a produc or se
making instead of buying a product, Coase said, a firm could avoid these costs and m
f the
than a reduction
ost Economics,
etic paradigm
thought to be
UTIONS OF
ation [under
tion were
abor is Limited By
nomic theory
firm does –
ol shared the
ies. See Robert H.
, 200 (1954)
t one level, or .
mple of such
l production, which
E
CONOMIC
7 (1959);
deed, as early as
o this as a “stock” example of a technological
determinant of vertical integration. See George J. Stigler, The Extent and Bases of
Monopoly, 32 A
M.ECON.REV. 1, 22 (1942) (“[T]he stock example [of vertical
integration producing economies] is the hot strip mill.”).
224
See Oliver E. Williamson, Delimiting Antitrust, 76 GEO. L.J. 271, 274 (1986)
(contending that Transaction Cost Economics and resulting reconception of the economic
origins of vertical integration was manifestation of a “genuine scientific revolution”).
225
See Coase, supra note 121, at 390-92.
distributive facilities by manufacturing firms. In most cases the rationale o
integration is evidently the increase of market power of the firms rather
in cost.”). See also Oliver E. Williamson, Technology and Transaction C
10 J. E
CON.BEH.&ORG. 355, 356 (1988) (asserting that under, price-theor
extant in the 1940s, 50s and 60s, “the ‘natural’ boundaries of the firm were
defined by engineering considerations.”); W
ILLIAMSON,ECONOMIC INSTIT
CAPITALISM, at 7-8 (“The prevailing orientation toward economic organiz
price theory] was that technological features of firm and market organiza
determinative.”); id. at 23-26, 86-89; George Stigler, The Division of L
the Extent of the Market, 59 J. P
OL.ECON. 185, 185 (1951) (stating that eco
has “generally treated as a (technological?) datum the problem of what the
what governs its range of activities or functions.”). Even the Chicago scho
belief that vertical integration produced only technological efficienc
Bork, Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act, 22 U. C
HI.L.REV. 157
(describing the benefits of vertical integration as “bypassing a monopoly a
. . enabling the achievement of internal efficiencies”). The stock exa
technological efficiencies was the integration of iron-making and stee
supposedly produced efficiencies by eliminating the need to reheat iron before feeding it
into a steel furnace. See F.M. S
CHERER,INDUSTRIAL STRUCTURE AND
PERFORMANCE, 70 (1970); JOE S. BAIN,INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, 156-5
CARL KAYSEN &DONALD TURNER,ANTITRUST POLICY, 120 (1959). In
1942, George Stigle ould refer tr w
84
reduce its overall cost of production.
226
omic actors to
me scholars
tion, are efficiency
estments and the
resulting vulnerability to post-transaction opportunism. Others additionally
recognized that vertical integration enabled coordinated adaptation and production that
Several decades later, scholars rediscovered Coase’s insight and proceeded to
identify a much wider range of “transaction costs” that might induce econ
forgo reliance on market organization in favor of firms.
227
For example, so
argued that committed vertical arrangements, including vertical integra
responses to transacting in the presence of relationship-specific inv
228
226
See id. at 390 (“The main reason why it is profitable to establish a fi
be that there is a cost of using the price mechanism.”).
227
Major contributions include: OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON,THE ECONOMI
OF
CAPITALISM (1985); Benjamin Klein, Robert Crawford, & Armen Alc
Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process
rm would seem to
C INSTITUTIONS
hian, Vertical
, 21 J.L. &
CO
f Production: Market
Bork, The Rule of
LE L.J. 373
L. & Econ. 86
Barak
onomics and
an & Jeffrey T.
pirical Research in the
r s, Courts, and
4 C
OLUM.L.
05);
Crawford, & Armen Alchian, Vertical Integration,
Appropriable Rents, And The Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. E
CON.&ORG.
297 (1978); OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON,MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES, 20-40, 82-105 (1975).
See also Oliver E. Williamson, The Logic of Economic Organization, 4 J.L. ECON.&
ORG. 65 (1988) (articulating mainstream view regarding rediscovery of Coase’s insight);
O
LIVER E. WILLIAMSON,ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM, at 31-32 (explaining
that, where asset specificity is absent, discrete market contracting functions well despite
bounded rationality and opportunism).
E
N. 297 (1978); Oliver E. Williamson, The Vertical Integration o
Failure Considerations, 61 A
M.ECON.REV. 112 (1971); Robert H.
Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division, 75 Y
A
(1965); Lester G. Telser, Why Do Manufacturers Want Fair Trade?, 3 J.
(1960).
The instant authors have also contributed to this literature. See e.g.
Richman, The Antitrust of Reputation Mechanisms: Institutional Ec
Concerted Refusals to Deal, 95 V
A.L.REV. 325 (2009); Barak D. Richm
Macher, “Transaction Cost Economics: An Assessment of Em
Social Sciences,” Business and Politics (2008); Barak D. Richman, Fi m
Reputation Mechanisms: Towards A Positive Theory of Private Ordering 10
R
EV. 2328 (2004); Alan J. Meese, Exclusive Dealing, Raising Rivals Costs and the
Theory of the Firm: Toward a New Synthesis, 50 ANTITRUST BULL. 371 (20
Monopolization, Exclusion and the Theory of the Firm, 89 M
INN.L.REV. 743 (2005);
Price Theory, Competition and the Rule of Reason, 2003 ILL.L.REV. 77.
228
See Benjamin Klein, Robert
85
market relationships could not produce. All of these arguments rested upon the
istic markets can invite certain market failures that
ver
ng antitrust
s vertical
an instance of
replacing a market transaction with administrative direction because the latter is believed
230
to partial and
dly rejected
g” rivals from access
to inputs or channels of distribution.
232
Instead these courts have adopted a much more
flexible and multi-factored approach that focus the inquiry on whether the vertical
229
assumption that transacting in atom
tical arrangements arise to correct.
Antitrust doctrine has properly followed suit. Prodded by leadi
scholars (Robert Bork once remarked that “[w]hat antitrust law perceives a
merger, and therefore as a suspect and probably traumatic event, is merely
to be a more efficient method of coordination” ), the Supreme Court and lower courts
have relaxed numerous doctrines from the inhospitality era that were hostile
complete integration.
231
Beginning in the late 1970s, courts have repeate
arguments that challenged mergers injure competition by “foreclosin
229
See, e.g.,OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON,THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPI
(1985).
230
ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 227 (1978). Bork is sig
expansive than Williamson, remarking that “Antitrust’s concern with vert
mistaken. . . . The vertical mergers the law currently outlaws have no effec
creation of efficiency.” Id. at 226.
TALISM
nificantly more
ical mergers is
t other than the
7) (reversing
522 U.S. 3
Jefferson Parish
. 2 (1985) (significantly increasing nature and
quantum of market power necessary to establish requisite element of tying case); Cont’l
T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) (reversing per se ban on exclusive
territories and location clauses).
232
See Alberta Gas Chems., 826 F.2d at 1244-46; Fruehauf Corp. v. FTC, 603 F.2d 345
(2d Cir. 1979); Crouse-Hinds Co. v. Internorth, 518 F. Supp. 416 (N.D.N.Y 1980); Crane
v. Harsco Corp., 509 F. Supp. 115, 125-26 (D. Del. 1981). See also United States v.
Loew’s, Inc., 882 F. 2d 29 (2d Cir. 1989).
231
See, e.g., Leegin Creative Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (200
96 year ban on minimum resale price maintenance); State Oil Co. v. Khan,
(1997) (reversing 28 year ban on maximum resale price maintenance);
Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S
86
arrangements meaningfully enshrine or expand market power. Applying this test,
es in which the
, supported,
duce competitive
erning vertical
n -horizontal
mergers are less likely than horizontal mergers to create competitive problems.”
235
ilarly declined to condemn vertical integration in evaluating claims that a
single firm has “monopolized” the market in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman
Act.
236
233
courts have routinely rejected challenges to vertical mergers, even in cas
vertical foreclosure was several times that which had, in previous decades
along with other factors, a finding that the merger would probably pro
harm.
234
At the same time, government enforcement guidelines gov
mergers reflected this new learning as well, expressly noting that “ on
Courts have sim
233
See Fruehauf, 603 F.2d at 353 (instructing courts to examine, among o
the “nature and economic purpose of the arrangement, the likelihood a
foreclosure, the extent of concentration of buyers and sellers in the i
cost required to enter the market, the market share needed by a buyer or sel
a profitable level of production (sometimes referred to as ‘scale economy’), the existence
of a trend toward vertical concentration or
ther factors,
nd size of market
ndustry, the capital
ler to achieve
whether the
To these
d by the
ngth of competing suppliers and purchasers.”); see also HTI Health
Miss. 1997)
merger that
rging parties);
d Section 7
ure).
ph continued
,” available at
http://www.ftc.gov/bc/international/docs/07RoundtableonVerticalMergers.pdf (noting
that “vertical mergers merit a stronger presumption of being efficient than do horizontal
mergers, and should be allowed to proceed except in those few cases where convincing,
fact-based evidence relating to the specific circumstances of the vertical merger indicates
likely competitive harm”).
236
See Belfiore v. N.Y. Times, 826 F.2d 177 (2d Cir. 1987) (rejecting claim that vertical
integration by a monopolist offended Section 2 of the Sherman Act despite negative
oligopoly in the industry, and
merger will eliminate potential competition by one of the merging parties.
factors may be added the degree of market power that would be possesse
enterprise and the stre
Servs., Inc. v. Quorum Health Group, Inc., 960 F. Supp. 1104, 1136 (S.D.
(articulating the same factors).
234
See Fruehauf, 603 F. 2d at 358-59 (rejecting FTC challenge to vertical
foreclosed rivals from selling 5.8% of the market’s output to one of the me
Crane Co., 509 F. Supp. at 125 (rejecting claim that vertical merger violate
despite 8.8% foreclos
235
See Department of Justice 1984 Merger Guidelines § 4.0. This paragra
“they are not invariably innocuous.” See also “Roundtable Submission
87
These are not, it should be emphasized, recent or untested developments, but
ent agencies
years ago that Judge
Ric by noting:
egory under
ons—that is,
arket or to
way it goes,
been using a
er to do the
on services.
a computer
service, it is
s. Vertical integration is a
ife and it would be absurd to make it a
suspect category under the antitrust laws just because it may hurt suppliers
Although vertical integration is often used to denote the merger of two economic
entities in sequential markets, it more accurately refers to a sp of relationships that
integration—
which includes mergers and acquisitions—is at one end of this spectrum with spot-market
238
middle. The
instead principles that are now fundamental to how courts and the enforcem
approach vertical integration. Indeed, it was more than twenty-five
hard Posner summarized the state of scholarship and antitrust law
Vertical integration is not an unlawful or even a suspect cat
the antitrust laws: ‘Firms constantly face ‘make or buy’ decisi
decisions whether to purchase a good or service in the m
produce it internally—and ordinarily the decision, whichever
raises no antitrust question.’ . . . .When a corporation that has
law firm to handle a particular type of litigation hires a lawy
litigation in house, it is vertically integrating into litigati
When a law firm that has been buying a billing service from
time-sharing firm buys its own computer to perform the
vertically integrating into computer service
universal feature of economic l
of the service that has been brought within the firm.
237
Scrutiny of Ticketmaster’s Vertical Agreements
ectrum
spans a diverse array of organizational arrangements. Complete vertical
transactions at the other, and a variety of intermediate forms, or “hybrid”
arrangements that reflect assorted levels of partial integration, occupy the
692 (8th Cir. 1984) (en
984) (Posner,
J.) (quoting Univ. Life Ins. Co. of America v. Unimarc Ltd., 699 F.2d 846, 852 (7th Cir.
1983)).
238
Oliver Williamson employed this term to describe arrangements that lie between the
“polar modes” of atomistic markets, on the on hand, and “hierarchy,” (complete vertical
integration), on the other. See O
LIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE MECHANISMS OF
GOVERNANCE, 104 (1996) (“hybrid” modes of economic organization include “various
forms of long-term contracting, reciprocal trading, regulation, franchising, and the like”).
impact on firm’s dealer); Paschall v. Kan. City Star Co., 727 F.2d
banc) (same).
237
See Jack Walters & Sons v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698 (7th Cir. 1
88
category of partially integrated hybrids includes long term contracts, exclusive contracts,
putational effects, joint ventures, cross-ownership, and an
asso
rs of ticket
clusive
ents. Both in the
past and recently, the exclusivity of these contracts has drawn some antitrust ire from
e contracts of this
secure incumbent
ave
hat the
share and stifled
entry possibilities from potential and smaller competitors.
241
Such critics therefore argue
that Ticketmaster’s use of exclusive contracts is anticompetitive and amounts to an
antitrust violation.
ns of anticompetitive conduct, most notably from Pearl Jam, caused the
tracting practices
repeated interactions with re
rtment of other arrangements.
Ticketmaster (as well as, we believe, other outsourced provide
distribution services) sells its ticket distribution services to venues under ex
contracts,
239
which are a species of partially integrated hybrid arrangem
commentators and attention from some antitrust enforcers. Exclusiv
kind, especially if extended for long periods of time, can sometimes
firms with monopoly power against competitive entry by rivals and thus h
anticompetitive consequences.
240
Some Ticketmaster critics have alleged t
company’s use of exclusive contracts has enshrined its leading market
Accusatio
Department of Justice to launch an investigation into Ticketmaster’s con
239
See supra, Part II.
240
See, e.g., United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 200 ive
vertical agreements by a market leader were also found to violate Sectio
States v. Microsoft, Inc., 253
5). Exclus
n 2 in United
F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam), but the
Microsoft court was particularly concerned about how exclusive agreements might
combine with the network externalities of the operating system market to lock in an
inferior technological standard. Network externalities of this sort do not appear to be
present in the market for ticket distribution services.
241
Balto Testimony, supra note 151, at 1 (“Ticketmaster’s monopoly power is preserved
through a series of exclusionary arrangements that diminish the potential for rivals to
arise and challenge the monopoly.”)
89
in 1994, but the investigation was closed the following year without any finding of
242
st Division
used for ticket
signate a single
assurances to
induce the distributor to make valuable investments in performing its services without
nwilling or
best seat
nd therefore knows
enabled Ticketmaster (and other distribution companies) to finance investments in
upgrading a venue’s ticketing facilities. Without an exclusive distribution period, which
also tends to appear in contracts negotiated by Ticketmaster’s rivals, the distribution
companies would be unwilling to sink upfront investments in improving a venue’s
ith a renewed appreciation for the
anticompetitive conduct. It seems likely, as one opponent of the transaction has
claimed, that the investigation was closed at least in part because the Antitru
recognized that exclusive contracts can yield identifiable efficiencies when
distribution.
243
Like other forms of vertical integration, contracts that de
ticket distributor as a venue’s exclusive distributor provide the necessary
fear that a follow-on distributor would exploit those investments. Consequently,
Ticketmaster is able to provide certain services that it otherwise would be u
unable to provide. For example, exclusivity enables distributors to offer “
available” searches, which are only possible if the distributor sells—a
the availability of—all of a performance’s tickets.
244
Exclusive arrangements have also
ticketing infrastructure.
245
Courts, in conjunction w
242
U.S. Ends Ticketmaster Investigation, N.Y. TIMES, July 6, 1995, at
Antitrust Division Statement, (July 5, 1995)
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press_releases/1995/0264.pdf.
C14. See also
243
See Balto Testimony, supra note 151, at 1-2.
244
See John Seabrook, The Price of the Ticket, NEW YORKER MAG., Aug. 10 & 17 2009,
at 34, 39 (with the exclusive right to sell tickets to a particular event, “Ticketmaster could
offer fans the best available seats, no matter where they purchased tickets”).
245
See Benjamin Klein, Robert Crawford and Armen Alchian, Vertical Integration,
Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297, 298-
302, 302-307 (1978). Cf. Broad. Music, Inc. v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 22 (1979) (fact that
90
efficiencies of restrictive vertical contracts and vertical integration, have long recognized
that ex
246
gements do limit a
y body of
mpetitive
rrent array of
exclusive contacts does not cause antitrust harm. A significant number of such contracts
et distributors
rs to be a
so small
ently, it is
arrangements
to block entry to the market. Although a venue might encounter some switching costs
when initiating a new contract with a different ticket distributor, there do not appear to be
he ticketing
s
clusive dealing arrangements can produce these and similar efficiencies.
Despite the efficiencies from exclusive contracts, such arran
potential competitive threat from rivals, so a complete evaluation of an
exclusive contracts would have to weigh the efficiencies against the antico
consequences. There is reason to believe, however, that Ticketmaster’s cu
expire each year, and venues regularly invite bids from alternative tick
before considering renewing with Ticketmaster. Moreover, there appea
relatively modest minimum viable scale for providing distribution services,
entrants do not require large volumes to offer profitable services. Consequ
likely difficult for any monopolist in ticket distribution to employ exclusive
247
any network externalities that would enable a hypothetical monopolist in t
business to enjoy cost advantages over entrants, nor are there interoperability concern
censes militated
1898) (Taft, J.),
sleeping car
xclusivity was
re the necessary investment of capital in the discharge of the duty”).
247
See IIA P. AREEDA ET AL., ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 421f at 68 (1995) (“[A]ll customers
might contract to buy exclusively from incumbents and yet allow effective entry if 20
percent of the contracts expire monthly or even annually.”). Cf. Gilbarco, Inc. v. Omega
Envtl., Inc., 127 F.3d 1157, 1162-64 (9th Cir. 1997) (no chance that exclusive dealing
contracts could foreclose competition among manufacturers for distributors where
contracts were of relatively short duration and manufacturers could offer dealers better
terms upon expiration).
smaller performing rights societies had also adopted so-called blanket li
against their automatic condemnation).
246
United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 287 (6th Cir.
aff’d 175 U.S. 211 (1899) (explaining that railroad could confer upon
company the exclusive right to provide railroad such cars and that such e
necessary “to secu
91
that create an industry-wide lock-in effect. Perhaps most significant, switching and
-
ontracts expire, and
ot appear to have
s from
Ticketmaster and its rivals. For these reasons, a court evaluating a rival’s claim that
t to accommodate their
mpetition, but for the mutual economic benefit of both
com which no antitrust
inferences may be drawn.”
However important it might be that Ticketmaster’s current use of exclusive
contracts does little to stifle entry and competition, the more important observation is that
of partial integration
248
negotiation costs evidently did not prevent a number of venues, including Live Nation
itself, from leaving one distributor and selecting a new one or choosing self
distribution.
249
Ticketmaster regularly loses clients as the exclusive c
the exclusive contracts—either individually or collectively—do n
deterred entry by firm hoping to wrest ticket distribution business away
250
Ticketmaster’s use of exclusive agreements foreclosed competition ruled that providers
of ticket distribution services use “the long term exclusive contrac
customers’ desires, to their mutual benefit…. [the] exclusive contract is not for the
purpose of excluding co
petitors. It is a mutually desired reasonable business practice from
251
these exclusive contracts generate identifiable efficiencies. This use
248
Cf. United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F. 3d 34, 54-56 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc)
ability
erected barriers to entry for
r Corp., 2003-1 Trade Cas. at 96,240-41 (describing vigorous
competition between providers of ticket distribution services); id. at 96,241(explaining
that the option of self-distribution via reliance on outside technology providers prevents
Ticketmaster from exercising market power).
250
See supra notes 79-111 and accompanying text (listing numerous examples of venues
that have recently taken on the task of distributing their own tickets).
251
Ticketmaster Corp. v. Tickets.com, Inc., 2003-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 74,013, at
96,241 (C.D. Cal. 2003).
(per curiam) (affirming district court’s finding that the benefits of interoper
contributed to Microsoft’s operating system monopoly and
new technological paradigms).
249
See Ticketmaste
92
hints at some additional benefits that might accompany the firms’ complete vertical
Eff
rs with
ine
ntrality of this
inquiry highlights that while some mergers are little more than shortcuts towards
the other. Even if economic
theo ry, an
ory suggests that
many efficiency motivations underlie the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger. It might
even be said, as a preliminary matter, that the companies were partially integrated by
icket distributor.
how exclusivity
nd services.
252
f Ticketmaster
with Live Nation is likely to create several additional efficiencies that might not be
erger-specific
efficiencies, all of which are consistent with economic theory, by themselves offer a
compelling endorsement of the proposed merger.
integration.
iciencies from Vertical Integration
Even though current antitrust law no longer views vertical merge
suspicion, it still inquires into the “nature and purpose of the agreement” to determ
whether efficiency motivations underlie a particular merger. The ce
extracting market rents, others are motivated by innovative possibilities and pursuing
efficiencies, and antitrust demands distinguishing one from
ry tells us that vertical mergers are presumptively in this second catego
efficiency analysis is still a routine element of any antitrust analysis.
An application of institutional economics and organizational the
contract, when exclusive contracts fixed Ticketmaster as Live Nation’s t
The efficiencies of that partial integration, discussed above, illustrate
facilitated valuable investments and the development of useful features a
A similarly motivated analysis suggests that the complete integration o
realized in their entirety without complete vertical integration. These m
252
See supra notes 244-246and accompanying text (discussing efficiencies achieved
from exclusive contracts).
93
1. Investments in Promotion and Information
tracts.
253
One
ially effort that is
e typical
investments
that would enhance the value of collective assets when the rewards from those marginal
investm
.
254
romoters. The
managers, and
nd other
products, but each party only receives a fraction of the revenue from each ticket sale.
Accordingly, each party is not optimally incentivized to invest the resources and effort to
ced ticket
a fraction of the
ng the value
ning tickets
and maximally utilize capacity. Vertical integration is one efficiency response to this
management,
and ticket sales, then it would be incentivized to make appropriate investments that would
It is well understood that vertical integration achieves efficiencies when it can
organize behavior that is effectively beyond the reach of arms-length con
element that frequently is listed as a “noncontractible” is effort, espec
invested to enhance the value of already-sunk investments. Parties, in th
collective action problem, routinely undersupply effort and other marginal
ents are shared by others. In other words, when team effort among separate
economic actors is required to maximize value, value is rarely maximized
This is precisely the situation that currently confronts concert p
several players along the value chain, including artists, promoters, venue
ticket distributors, all benefit from maximizing revenues from ticket sales a
maximize value for the team. To be sure, Ticketmaster and other outsour
distributors enjoy a commission for each ticket sold, but this fee is only
overall cost of the ticket, and thus the distributor (like every other actor alo
chain) is underincentivized to invest in the promotion required to sell remai
coordination problem. If a single firm is responsible for promotion, venue
253
See, e.g., OLIVER HART, PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE NATURE OF THE FIRM (1988).
254
See, e.g., Bengt Holmstrom, Moral Hazard in Teams, 13 BELL J. ECON. 324 (1982);
Ilya Segal, Contracting with Externalities, 114 Q.J. ECON. 337 (1999).
94
improve efficiency, thus increasing both revenue for the performers and the collective
welfare of all those in th
iciencies that
ments. One
unfilled capacity in
nificant
unutilized capacity and lost income to the venues, promoters, and artists. One potential
. If the returns
allocated, parties are unlikely to invest the
req would reap greater
Similar coordination problems might be responsible for impeding valuable
innovations along the value chain. For example, intensified advertising is only one
ers might
fan base, such that
ts. Investments in
ng information that
increases capacity, also are vulnerable to a collective action problem that could be
e principle also applies to other revenue
sources, such as merchandise sales, that could be enhanced by obtaining better
information about a fan base. Because investments in the effort and resources necessary
e value chain.
The live entertainment industry currently shows evidence of ineff
could be reduced by improving incentives to make value-enhancing invest
significant and growing industry-wide challenge, for example, is the
concert halls.
255
These empty seats and unpurchased tickets represent sig
solution to reducing excess capacity is to make additional investments in advertising and
publicity, especially in the form of targeted promotions for specific shows
from such targeted promotion are diffusely
uisite effort and resources. Alternatively, an integrated promoter
returns and is more likely to seek greater capacity.
potential solution to the problem of unsold tickets, described above. Oth
include investing in marketing research or acquiring information on a
promotional activities could be directed at specific consumer segmen
this sort of research, and any investments in acquiring or distributi
mitigated by vertical integration. The sam
255
Krueger, supra note 9, at 12.
95
to obtain and disseminate new information are so difficult to specify by contract, vertical
ed Comcast-Spectacor, attested to these same
effi
revenue have been
nment
industry, and the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger has been characterized as an effort to
mec rties from
making the necessary investments to appropriate these revenue opportunities.
2. Cooperative Adaptation to Meet Artists’ Demands, Respond to Market
city to
pursue cooperative adaptation. That is, when unforeseen changed circumstances,
including those that are common in a rapidly evolving industry, necessitate adjustments
facilitate the
integration arises as a useful mechanism to increase efficiency along a value chain. Peter
Luukko, Chairman of vertically integrat
ciencies in his testimony before Congress.
256
Decreasing the excess capacity and pursuing new sources of
described as two central challenges that currently confront the live entertai
pursue both opportunities. Economic theory confirms that vertical integration is one
hanism that can overcome collective action problems that prevent pa
Changes, & Pursue Innovations
Another organizational feature that vertical integration exhibits is the capa
by numerous co-venturers, integration with within a single entity can
256
Peter Lukko, President and Chief Operating Officer, Comcast-Spectaco
Statement Before the U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on th
Subcommittee on Courts and Competition, at 2-3 (Feb. 26, 2009) (“By
company that owns, manages, and/or operates venues, owns several sports t
other content, and provides its ow
r, L.P.,
e Judiciary,
being part of a
eams and
n ticketing solution and food and beverage services to
arenas, stadiums and amphitheatres throughout the country, we have the ability to cross-
promote among these different levels in the vertical distribution chain and to touch the
fan directly at multiple points in his or her sports/entertainment experience. Additionally,
because we have more assets in some cities like Philadelphia, we have the ability to
create unique packages to offer to sponsors and fans alike. This is where the industry
trend is clearly moving—in large part because content providers want to have more direct
control of the connection to their fans.”).
96
required adaptation. For these circumstances, vertical integration serves as a more
efficient org
257
performances,
increasingly
vertically
er media that
would help them shape their image and disseminate their music. Such coordinated efforts
ight be
ho place value
rdination of concert promotions,
mer es to manage these
Coordinated adaptation would also facilitate a collective reprioritization of
promotional effort, and thus could also mitigate lost revenues from underutilization of
able sums for
ticket sales for
l
kets
258
—would have
s. This is because
and therefore
cannot specify how ticket distributors should direct consumer inquiries. Vertical
anizational form than alternatives.
Given the growing number of parties involved in producing live
coordination might be especially valuable to artists who find themselves
separated from fans as new market segments enter the production chain. A
integrated infrastructure would give artists access to communication and oth
to promote merchandise, concerts tickets, and other reputational goods m
especially important for artists who target certain distinctive fan bases or w
in managing a particular brand image. The coo
chandise sales, and other initiatives would enhance artists’ abiliti
activities that are commonly so important to performers.
capacity in concerts. Outsourced ticket distributors generally make compar
selling tickets of any sort, so they might not be incentivized to promote
performances with substantial capacity remaining. Under these contractua
arrangements, promoters—who feel most of the pain from unsold tic
difficulty directing distributors to promote sales for certain concert
promoters, at the time ticket distribution contracts are signed, do not know
257
See, e.g., CHESTER I. BERNARD, THE FUNCTIONS OF THE EXECUTIVE (1954).
258
As discussed above, see supra Part II, the first dollar revenues generated by a
performances goes to the band as a “guaranteed advance.” Only after this guaranteed
advance is paid does the promoter share in any revenue generated by the performance.
97
integration enables the coordination of promotion efforts along the value chain and could
er
s by targeting
gh mechanisms
adaptation,
mstances after activities already commence, is a central
economic benefit to vertical integration.
ies. For
ticketing,” in
lue for a ticket
r, securing an
innovative pricing scheme, which would require new contractual relationships between
artists (and their managers), promoters, venues, and ticket distributors, might require
ith multiple
y resisting change
such coordinated
accordingly
often pursued by vertically integrated entities. Although the literature regarding how
organizations spur innovation is extensive, complicated, and replete with different
conclusions, certainly it is plausible that innovations such as end-price ticketing and other
creative reorganizations of ticket pricing would be pursued more effectively by a
vertically integrated value chain.
therefore respond effectively to unanticipated market developments and consum
behavior. Vertically integrated promoters can flexibly adjust to initial sale
shows that have substantial numbers of available tickets, especially throu
that give promoters direct contact with ticket purchasers. Such coordinated
which responds to changing circu
The ability to coordinate the many actors in the live entertainment value chain
could also lead to innovations that might generate new revenue opportunit
example, Ticketmaster has said that consumers would prefer “end-price
which ticket purchasers are quoted a single end price rather than a face va
upon which taxes, service fees, and other additions are added. Howeve
coordination and collective investments that may be difficult to engineer w
parties. This is especially true if any one party could extort the others b
and holding out for a disproportionate share. Innovations that require
investments and collaborative information sharing from multiple parties are
98
3. Targeted Linkages Between Venues, Entertainers, and Fans
sts with their
the possibilities
creators of live
ostly, and
perhaps impossible, to achieve under the current fragmented industry structure.
eir fan base.
261
This
nd serve a
diverse and increasingly mobile fan base.
d thus less
The CEOs of both Ticketmaster and Live Nation have stated repeatedly in public
that the merger’s objective is to develop new and better avenues to link arti
fans.
259
These statements of “linkages,” and other statements suggesting
of creating “new content,”
260
reflect the perception that connecting the
entertainment with their fans can create desirable activities that are very c
Firms that offer ticket distribution technology advertise that self-distribution
empowers venues with a complete and thorough understanding of th
is even truer for promoters like Live Nation that own numerous venues a
The information garnered about ticket
purchasers from Internet sales can facilitate the development of targeted an
259
Michael Rapino, President & Chief Executive Officer, Live Nation, Wr
Testimony Before the Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy of t
Committee on the Judiciary, CQ Financial Transcripts (Feb. 26, 2009) (“Th
help bring about the reconfiguration we urgently need. . . . Artists would b
itten
he House
is merger can
e able to
ce with new
ster, supra note 1
ip of fans to
velop that bond
the House
company "will
hance the fan
ms of entertainment more accessible to everyone").
261
http://www.veritix.com/solutions/ticket_event_marketing.aspx (“Veritix offers the
most advanced marketing and data management tools in the industry, which means you'll
know more about your customers than ever before”); www.neweratickets.com/why-
net/whynet/you-own-your-data/ ("One of the first steps in marketing success is owning
your customer data. . . . New Era Tickets provides a fully integrated and sophisticated
database marketing product with your ticketing system that helps you use your customer
data to increase sales.").
communicate directly with fans, and have the flexibility to experien
approaches to deliver music.”); Press Release, Live Nation & Ticketma
(“There is nothing more magical than the bond and the intimate relationsh
artists. It is truly an experience that needs to be embraced and nurtured with both integrity
and respect. One of the mandates of the combined company will be to de
to unsurpassed levels.”).
260
Id.; Irving Azoff, Chief Executive Officer, Ticketmaster Entertainment, Inc.,
Testimony Before the Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy of
Committee on the Judiciary at 4 (Feb. 26, 2009) (Explaining the merged
be better able to develop new and innovative products and services that en
experience and make all for
99
costly marketing strategies. Such information about the demands and preferences of a
262
moters would be
rest in the
eir fan base such that
would
complement their performances. These interactions not only amount to new goods and
content; they also create com e
other sources
many
tion would seem
to enable a valuable business platform for marketing multiple sources of content, goods,
and services. Perhaps an important question is, if joining these sources of information
ready entered
information-sharing agreements to learn from each other’s consumer data and jointly
oter is
erally
fan base also lays the ground work for the promotion of complementary goods and
services such as recorded music, apparel, and other merchandise. Pro
able to selectively market products to fans who have expressed specific inte
promoted artists. Artists too can communicate and interface with th
they can both receive fan feedback and disseminate communications that
plementarities to the concert experience that enhance th
quality of live performances.
Information on ticket purchasers would likely enhance the value of
of consumer information, such as data on music or merchandise sales that
promoters have. The synthesis of multiple sources of consumer informa
could be so valuable, why Ticketmaster and Live Nation have not al
launch an e-commerce platform. Although a merger of the distributor and prom
one way to unite the complementary commercial interests, antitrust law gen
262
Acquiring information on ticket purchasers can easily support parallel revenue
sources. The Tessitura Network, for example, offers ticketing software that is tailored for
the needs of non-profit organizations that produce arts and cultural entertainment. Its
software “fully integrate[s] in one database ticketing, fundraising, memberships,
marketing, reporting, customer relationship management, Web transactions, custom
capabilities and more.” See http://www.tessituranetwork.com/Products.aspx. Tessitura
offers one illustration of how gathering information on ticket purchasers creates value for
other organizational objectives.
100
requires parties (before claiming merger-specific efficiencies) to first entertain whether
an alterna
d the venues
icies that would
e Ticketmaster’s
the merger were
prohibited it is possible that these contracts would emerge. However, Internet
at a
an Internet
fining property
to contract for,
ilar to the general problem, described
above, that results in suboptimal promotion) that deters the complete development of a
useful database of fan preferences and consumer behaviors.
atform is that a
tary
r making sunk
e for an
alternative distributor. Mitigating the hazards of such exposure is often difficult to do by
many risks that
are difficult to anticipate. Under such circumstances, vertical integration offers a reliable
tive that is less restrictive to a merger would achieve the same efficiencies.
It does seem possible that careful contracts between Ticketmaster an
it services—contracts that carefully define property rights and privacy pol
govern the consumer information for particular fan bases—could enabl
clients to pursue these revenue opportunities absent a merger, and if
263
marketing has consumed e-commerce for nearly a decade, and it is surprising th
successful technology company like Ticketmaster has not developed such
platform for clients that are highly tuned to emerging markets. Perhaps de
rights and privacy policies are either noncontractible or extremely costly
or perhaps there is a collective action problem (sim
Another potential explanation for the lack of an e-commerce pl
Ticketmaster client might fear being beholden to Ticketmaster after proprie
information on its fans is assembled, or conversely, Ticketmaster might fea
investments in acquiring such information only to see a client will then leav
contract given that a contractual solution would have to anticipate a great
263
Scott Masten, A Legal Basis for the Firm, 4 J.L. ECON.&ORG. 181, 194-95 (1988)
(observing that, in theory, multiple parties can always replicate the activities of the firm
by entering into, monitoring, and perfectly enforcing multiple contracts).
101
solution. An integrated entity would not suffer from imprecise property rights or
entarities of, and the optimal incentives to produce and acquire, such consumer
info
not yet
uld permit, and
one ready explanation is that contracts could not provide both companies the necessary
ise of new
ations, and
merger, so one
rtunities if
ave. Vertical integration certainly would enable them to pursue these new
markets, and there is good reason to suspect that without complete integration they might
be unattainable.
ntegration is
ing across the
t such an
industry-wide trend can constitute prima facie evidence that vertical integration generates
btaining or
protecting market power are pursuing such integration strategies, this trend is especially
proprietary concerns over consumer information, and it would assuredly capitalize on the
complem
rmation.
In any event, it is curious that two highly successful companies have
managed to construct an e-commerce platform that current technology wo
security from expropriation of property rights or sunk investments. The prom
content and fan-oriented complementarities seem to be compelling motiv
perhaps more than any other factor are the primary motivation behind the
would expect that the companies would have previously pursued these oppo
they could h
4. Industry-wide Vertical Integration
Perhaps the most convincing evidence of efficiencies from vertical i
that vertical acquisitions and integration strategies appear to be spread
industry. Antitrust law and the enforcement agencies have recognized tha
substantial efficiencies.
264
When, as here, firms without any chance of o
264
Dept. of Justice 1984 Merger Guidelines, § 4.24 (“An extensive pattern of vertical
integration may constitute evidence that substantial economies are afforded by vertical
integration.”).
102
suggestive that the organizational shift reflects the realization of efficiencies not
otherwise obtainable via traditiona
265
is becoming an
Self-
d companies
market power)
justifications. But recent years have also witnessed an assortment of vertical integration
ainment closer to their respective fan bases, not just through ticket distribution but
me examples
e NHL Colorado
Dick’s Sporting
l company, and
x Sports
ore than 2 million
households across the mountain west and created its own network called
Altitude Sports & Entertainment. In 2007, KSE unveiled TicketHorse
adium, a year
alanche would
begin utilizing Veritix’s ticketing platform beginning in July 2009.
266
l methods of ticket distribution.
As is discussed extensively in Section III, self-distribution
increasingly popular mechanism for venues to sell tickets to their events.
distribution strategies are being pursued by small and large venues alike, an
advertising the merits of self-distribution offer compelling efficiency (not
strategies that have brought venues, promoters, sports teams, and other producers of live
entert
also through broadcasting and an assortment of Internet-based products. So
include:
1. Kroenke Sports Entertainment (“KSE”) owns and operates th
Avalanche, NBA Denver Nuggets, MLS Colorado Rapids,
Goods Park stadium, Paramount Theatre, Opera Shop theatrica
the Denver’s Pepsi Center. In 2004, Kroenke dropped the Fo
Network, which had delivered games of KSE teams to m
(powered by Veritix) as to service all events at KSE’s soccer st
later KSE announced that the Pepsi Center, Nuggets, and Av
265
Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm: Influence, 4 J.L. ECON.&ORG
(1988) (competition between economic actors will result in optimal degree
integration).
266
See Kroenke Sports Enterprises Extends Deal with Vertix, TicketNews
2008), available at
. 33, 39-40
of vertical
(July 31,
tp://www.ticketnews.com/node/3411; Greg Griffin & Robert
Sanchez, A Look Inside Kroenke’s Empire, Denverpost.com (July 8, 2007), available at
http://www.denverpost.com/null/ci_6318716. Kroenke Sports Executive Vice President
Paul Andrews noted the value of vertical integration when he remarked, “[u]ltimately, we
want the success or failure of that fan’s experience to begin and end with us . . . . We can
get you that ticket to the Rapids game; we can get you inside a great stadium; we can get
you out of the parking lot quickly after the game; and when you get home, you can watch
the highlights on TV.” Id.
ht
103
2. Comcast-Spectacor is a growing sports and entertainment ventur
includes the Philadelphia Flyers, the Philadelphia 76ers, the AH
Phantoms, the Wachovia Center, and a 24-hour regional spor
network, Comcast SportsNet. In 2003, Comcast-Spectacor used
enablement solutions to develop New Era Tickets, a full-service
company. In addition to these ventures, Comcast-Spectacor
marketing services com
e that
L Philadelphia
ts programming
Paciolan's
ticketing
also operates two
panies – Front Row Marketing Services (corporate
sponsorships) and 3601 Creative Group (full-service marketing
ted by Major
February
ent to purchase
g, allowing fan's
content,
ll phones.
268
ctober 2002, by
t media company in the Spanish-speaking world,
and Corporacion Interamericana de Entretenimiento, the leading live
U.S. market.
certs for
communications agency).
267
3. Major League Baseball Advanced Media (“MLBAM”) was crea
League Baseball in 2000 to operate baseball's digital assets. In
2005, MLB announced MLBAM had reached an agreem
Tickets.com, which two years later introduced mobile ticketin
to receive ticket bar codes on their cell phones. MLB.com also offers live-
streaming of all regular season games and other MLB-related
including services that send content directly to subscribers’ ce
4. OCESA Entretenimiento is a strategic alliance, formed in O
Grupo Televisa, the larges
entertainment company in Latin America, Spain, and the Latin
The deal vertically integrates the ticketing and promotion for con
Televisa's roster of Latino stars.
269
267
See http://www.comcast-spectacor.com/CompanyHistory.asp. Comcast-Spectaco
annual summary notes that “the resources of other Comcast-Spectacor co
a synergy that greatly benefits Global Spectrum clients. Whether it’s by c
finding and developing naming rights and evaluating sponsorship opportunities (Front
r’s
mpanies create[]
reating events,
cessions
out-of-the-box
ets), Global
ent Experience,
ODAY, Dec. 5,
baseball-
eague Baseball Agrees to
r Fans,
InternetNews.com, Feb. 15, 2005, available at http://www.Internetnews.com/ec-
news/article.php/3483356.
269
Simeon Tegel, Televisa's CIE stake OK'd, Deal joins ticketing, live entertainment
businesses, VARIETY, June 26, 2003, available at http://www.variety.com/index.asp?
layout=print_story&articleid=VR1117888535&categoryid=1237. The companies state
that the merger was motivated the prospect of developing new content and
complimentary products. See Press Release, Grupo Televisa and CIE Form Strategic
Row Marketing Services), establishing new revenue sources through con
improvements and upgrades (Ovations Food Services) or engaging in
thinking about new ticketing and technology breakthroughs (New Era Tick
Spectrum maximizes revenue potential and attracts a greater number of visitors at the
venues it manages.” Comcast Spectacor: Providing a Total Entertainm
Annual Summary (2009), at 11.
268
Jorge L. Ortiz, MLB’s Advanced Media Arm Pulls in Profits, USA T
2007, available at http://www.usatoday.com/sports/baseball/2007-12-04-
online_N.htm; Tim Gray, MLB Acquires Tickets.com: Major L
Purchase the Ticket Seller to Make the Ticket-Buying Process Easier fo
104
5. Edgar Bronfman, Jr., CEO of Warner Music Group, suggeste
record label will expand into downstream markets in an expa
market and sell music and music products. Bronfman said th
taking steps to offer ticketing services, touring, merchandising, f
management, sponsorship, and artist management. Warner Music also has
d recently the
nded effort to
e company is
an club
adopted a “360 strategy” that acquires all revenue streams for an artist’s music
rights, including ticketing, touring, merchandise, and sponsorship.
270
industry at
large, but at minimum they illustrate that the Live Nation-Ticketmaster transaction is one
live
both vibrant and
et power and
sortment of
spite the diversity of
players moving towards vertical integration, they all seem to state parallel motivations
and seek the same category of efficiencies in their organizational strategies.
Con ikely to result from a
Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger.
tee on
It is difficult to determine how accurately these developments represent the
of several similar organizational developments in the vertical integration of
entertainment. It is significant that this trend has included companies in
struggling economic sectors, companies that might plausibly enjoy mark
companies that in all likelihood have little-to-no market power, and an as
strategies that bring performers and content to end-users. Yet de
sequently, they strongly hint at some of the efficiencies that are l
Addressing Critics of the Live Nation-Ticketmaster Transaction
On July 27, Senator Herb Kohl, Chairman of the Senate Subcommit
and Televisa will
nment vertical integration model, the
production and promotion of the best quality concerts, theatrical, family and cultural
events, as well as the operation of entertainment venues, the sale of entrance tickets, food,
beverage and souvenirs, and the organization of special, and corporate events.”).
270
Warner Music Group Corp F1Q08 (Qtr End 12/31/08) Earnings Call Transcript,
http://seekingalpha.com/article/118835-warner-music-group-corp-f1q08-qtr-end-12-31-
08; Caroline McCarthy, Warner's Bronfman, MySpace's DeWolfe Talk Music,
http://news.cnet.com/8301-13577_3-10084715-36.html.
Alliance for Live Entertainment In Mexico (Oct. 18, 2002) (“CIE
benefit from the advantages of the live entertai
105
Antitrust, sent a letter to Assistant Attorney General Christine Varney to convey his
s competition
271
ilar letter to Assistant
e of
sed transaction
siness managers,
artists, independent promoters, and music fans in every state are likely to suffer if the
272
ns of recent opposition to the
pro mon arguments
in agency
ed its ire at
Ticketmaster. In 1994, congressional hearings featured Pearl Jam’s testimony decrying
Ticketmaster’s pricing policies. These events illustrate the interesting tension between
mands made on
e are addressed
the consolidation of
n in the market for
iencies created in
this industry by vertical integration, with one letter using “vertically integrated
belief that the proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger “presents seriou
concerns.” That same day, Congressman Bill Pascrell sent a sim
Attorney General Varney, signed by fifty of his colleagues in the U.S. Hous
Representatives, that “urge[d] the Justice Department to analyze this propo
closely and with great skepticism” and concluded that “[c]onsumers, bu
merger is allowed to occur.” These letters were reflectio
posed Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger and articulate the most com
predicting that the merger will lead to anticompetitive consequences.
This is not the first time that congressional politics has intervened
merger review and not even the first time congressional politics has focus
proper applications of antitrust law and popular (and often politicized) de
the enforcement agencies.
Most of the arguments that the letters—and other critics—articulat
in the sections above. Both letters, for example, express fears that
two current and future competitors will reduce horizontal competitio
ticket distribution services. Both letters also fail to recognize the effic
271
See Kohl Letter, supra note 4 (asserting that Live Nation “start[ed] a ticketing
business to compete with Ticketmaster (and as a result sold 5.8 million tickets in the first
four months of 2009). If the merger occurs, this direct competition will be lost.”).
272
Pascrell Letter, supra note 4.
106
entertainment giant” as a pejorative term. This section focuses on two arguments that
rations of
entity to exploit
nt economic
utes these typical claims, and it similarly undermines the two arguments we
address here.
med that the
ion and harm
tion, it is said, the
new entity will condition access to Ticketmaster’s ticket distribution services on venues’
agreement also to book only Live Nation-promoted acts, thereby foreclosing other
pro
275
, these critics
omoters they
ld essentially amount to what one might call “a theory of
nder Section 1 of the Sherman
ve held parties liable for arrangements tha
273
are conveyed in the letters and by other critics yet are not addressed directly by the
previous sections. Importantly, these two particular arguments are also ite
common—and mistaken—fears that vertical mergers will enable a new
its presence in one market to create unfair advantages in another. Curre
theory ref
1. Leveraging Market Power from Ticket Distribution to Concert Promotion
Critics of the proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger have clai
transaction will empower the merged entity to leverage its monopoly position in the
market for ticket distribution services to anticompetitively expand its posit
competition in the market for concert promotion.
274
After the transac
moters from doing business with these venues. Put another way
predict that the new entity will be in a position to force venues to replace pr
currently retain with Live Nation.
Such conduct wou
prospective tying.” Tying, of course, is already regulated u
c tA t, and while most ties are lawful, courts ha
273
Kohl Letter, supra note 4.
274
Kohl Letter, supra note 4 (“[I]ndependent concert promoters may find it very difficult
to attract artists who could otherwise use the vertically integrated Live
Nation/Ticketmaster for its range of services.”). See also Balto Testimony, supra note
151.
275
See Balto Testimony, supra note 151.
107
create an undue risk of anticompetitive harm. So-called “anticompetitive forcing,” that
the
277
t the merged
obability of such tying, then perhaps it would be appropriate to
cha
ew entity will
possess economic power in the ticket distribution market, and therefore is unlikely to be
279
erged
ation, such as cross-
was to bundle
artists and
s not coercively use
rice of the
276
is, the use of the seller’s economic power over the tying product to coerce purchase of
tied product, is one such tying violation. If the evidence indicated tha
entity creates a high pr
llenge it on that basis.
278
However, as is explained in Part III, supra, it is doubtful that the n
able to coerce purchasers of live entertainment promotion. To be sure, the m
entity would be entitled to reap the benefits flowing from such integr
marketing products, and many of the stated purposes of seeking the merger
goods and services such that multiple revenue streams would accrue to
promoters.
280
Such bundling of goods is permissible so long as it doe
market power to force purchases for reasons unrelated to the quality and p
276
See Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984). Som
arrangements are still deemed to be per se violations. Id.
277
See Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 14-16 (describing purported harm fro
contracts in this manner). See also Fortner Enter. v. U.S. Steel, 429 U
(same).
e tying
m such tying
.S. 610 (1977)
s determination
ealing between
tial suppliers to
18 F. Supp. 416,
mine whether vertical
demnation).
ation Merger,
venue operators that
Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger would not suppress competition in promotion market
and that promoters would still bring live entertainment to small venues); cf. Jefferson
Parish, 466 U.S. at 26-29 (holding that 30 percent share of the relevant market did not
constitute economic power sufficient to establish per se tying violation).
280
See supra notes 44-47 and accompanying text (describing the heightened economic
significance of developing, and the corresponding plans to develop, Internet platforms to
jointly market and distribute concert tickets with accompanying merchandise).
278
Cf. FTC v. Consol. Foods Corp., 380 U.S. 592 (1965) (affirming FTC’
that merger violated Section 7 because it resulted in probable reciprocal d
the remaining firm and its customers, thereby disadvantaging other poten
these same customers). See also Crouse-Hinds Co. v. Internorth, Inc., 5
442-43 (N.D.N.Y. 1981) (applying such a framework to deter
transaction would result in a propensity of tying that would justify its con
279
See On the Case: DOJ Quizzes Live Venues about Ticketmaster-Live N
BILLBOARD, Aug. 22, 2009 (reporting confidence of several small
108
products offered. But the mere prospect of bundled sales does not implicate the
possible only from the exercise of coercion that the merged
enti
282
be would make little
icket
opoly by subsidizing
inefficient entry into the promotion market. Rudimentary industrial organization
economics instruct that a monopolist’s profit-maximizing strategy is to market its
281
Clayton Act. A violation is
ty does not seem to have.
More fundamentally, the sort of conduct these critics descri
economic sense. Assuming the merged entity has monopoly power in the t
distribution market, it would be diluting the profitability of that mon
281
See Berkey Photo Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 276 (2
large firm does not violate § 2 [of the Sherman Act] simply by reaping the com
rewards attributable to its efficient size, nor does an integrated business of
Sherman Act whenever one of its departments benefits from association wi
possessing a monopoly in its own market. So long as we allow a firm to co
several fields, we must expect it to seek the competitive advantages of
activity – more efficient production, greater ability to develop compleme
reduced transaction costs, and so forth. These are gains that accrue to any i
firm, regardless of its market share, and they cannot by themselv
d Cir. 1979) (“[A]
petitive
fend the
th a division
mpete in
its broad-based
ntary products,
ntegrated
es be considered uses of
package sales so
Ry. Co. v.
either product by
ms as a unit at
.
tend on
erge to do so.
tion, in which
t use the
arrangements by
ing as unfair trade
ice arrangement whereby oil company coerced its dealers into stocking and
promoting tires, batteries and accessories manufactured by Goodyear), and even the
leading tying decision in the past three decades involved a contract-based tying
arrangement, Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 5-8 (holding liable a hospital that allegedly
required its surgery patients to employ anesthesiologists employed by an independent
firm selected by the hospital). Such a policy would have the very same effect (or lack
thereof) on competition in the promotion market as would the consummation of this
merger.
monopoly power.”). This even applies to monopolists, who may make
long as the purchaser’s purchase of the package is voluntary. See N. Pac.
United States, 356 U.S. 1, 6 (1958) (“Where the buyer is free to take
itself there is no tying problem even though the seller may offer the two ite
a single price.”); Marts v. Xerox, Inc., 77 F. 3d 1109 (8th Cir. 1996) (same)
282
It is worth noting that even if Ticketmaster and Live Nation did in
implementing a coercive tying arrangement, they would not have to m
Instead, they could simply pursue such a strategy via contractual coopera
Ticketmaster would only provide ticket distribution services to firms tha
independent Live Nation as a promoter. Some firms have pursued tying
contract, see, e.g., Atl. Refining Co. v. FTC, 381 U.S. 357 (1965) (bann
pract
109
monopolized product independently. Moreover, this strategy also is vulnerable to
ould alienate many
likely
ificant spread of
edium term
contracts, either with ticket distribution firms or suppliers of software that support self-
ire the
romises made today several years from now, when conditions
faci d not be a wise,
ed several
regional promoters and operators of small-to-midsized venues who feared being
continually outbid by an industry giant. Of course, outbidding competitors is part of the
re important, a
es who can
ation’s merger with
nment content
s evidence of efficiencies
not
anticompetitive—advantage over its rivals. Smaller venue operators and promoters
283
common sense scrutiny. Requiring venues to deal with an unwanted promoter as a
condition of employing the new entity’s ticket distribution services w
venues and effectively increase raise the price of its distribution services. A
consequence would be a migration of business to competitors or the sign
additional self-distribution.
284
And because many venues are subject to m
distribution, such a tying strategy would face a temporal problem, as it would requ
new entity to enforce p
ng venues may well have changed. In the most basic sense, it woul
profit-maximizing strategy.
The congressional hearings examining the proposed merger includ
competitive process and translates into greater revenues for artists. Mo
competitive bidding process means that promoters who win bids are the on
generate the greatest revenue from those live performers. If Live N
Ticketmaster or its access to upstream markets and creators of entertai
enables it to outbid its competitors, then such bidding success i
that accrued from vertical integration and is a product of a procompetitive—
283
JEAN TIROLE, THE THEORY OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION §8.4 (1997).
284
See Fruehauf, 603 F.2d at 355 (rejecting FTC’s conclusion that entity would favor its
own downstream purchaser in time of shortage because such tactics would risk customer
retaliation that would cause the new entity “greater economic harm”).
110
might be advised to seek similar vertical integration strategies to obtain comparable
-enhancing merger
ance a rival’s competitiveness is antithetical to the aims of the
nati
Congressional critics of the transaction have also claimed that a Live Nation-
fects in the
arket for
concert promotion. These critics suggest that harm to the market for ticket distribution
irm will force
efficiencies, and pursuing such strategies would make them part of the industry-wide
trend towards vertical integration. But seeking to block an efficiency
because it might enh
on’s antitrust laws.
285
2. Foreclosing Competition in Ticket Distribution
Ticketmaster merger will reduce competition and thus produce harmful ef
market for ticket distribution, separate and apart from any impact on the m
will occur through two mechanisms. First, they argue that the integrated f
285
Live Nation’s competitors—and Senator Kohl’s letter to Assistant A
Varney—expressed a related concern about how a Live Nation-Ticketmast
might affect competition in the promotion market. See Kohl Letter, su
Nation/Ticketmaster will automatically have valuable information about in
promoters' business, such as customer email addresses, demographics of co
and pricing of tickets, which they can use to directly compete for concert pr
business.”); see also Hurwitz Testimony,supra note 2. Many of th
ttorney General
er merger
pra note 4 (“Live
dependent
ncertgoers,
omotion
ese smaller promoters
ibutor, and
s and their fan base over
perators, who
Entertainment will
ge fair
d, though we
n artists and
at an expropriation of this data would
violate the terms of the service contract that Ticketmaster signed when agreeing to
provide distribution services, and thus the merged company would be prohibited from
improperly exploiting the data. Moreover, the Federal Trade Commission’s Bureau of
Consumer Protection monitors business use of private information, and any misuse of
data by Live Nation Entertainment would invite appropriate scrutiny from that office. In
short, there appear to be other legal means to prevent the misappropriation of private data
in addition to preventing an otherwise efficient merger.
and venues had previously contracted with Ticketmaster as a ticket distr
Ticketmaster consequently acquired information on these venue
the course of providing distribution services. These promoters and venue o
are competitors with Live Nation, now fear that a merged Live Nation
have access to give proprietary information to their competitor and dama
competition in the market for live entertainment promotion.
We have no evidence suggesting whether these fears are well-founde
suspect that violating the trust of former clients would not help Live Nation
Entertainment’s commercial success as it aims to acquire new information o
fans throughout the country. We do suspect th
111
Ticketmaster services upon independent concert promoters, consequently reducing
286
erger will
tion services of the merged entity,
thu
argument:
rket power in
ticket distribution to harm competition in the promotion market, this argument suggests
ain that a
s anticompetitive
inary matter,
properly
defined market for promotion. Because Ticketmaster does not currently participate in the
market for promotion of live entertainment, the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger would
ill be no more
here have been no
alle bution services to its
tion remains very
small), then there is little reason to fear competitive harm after the merger.
undle
promotion with ticket distribution, it makes little economic sense to bundle ticket
opportunities for competing ticket distributors, and second, that the m
effectively commit Live Nation to using the distribu
s depriving other distributors of that substantial business.
This first theory might be considered the flip-side of the previous
whereas some critics fear that the merger will enable the leveraging of ma
that the merged firm will leverage market power in the promotion market to harm
competition in ticket distribution. At the risk of being repetitive, we note ag
theory of “prospective tying” is colorable only if market power enable
forcing that coerces purchases of a tied product or service. Thus, as a prelim
that this theory requires a showing that Live Nation has market power in a
not change that market’s concentration, and therefore the merged entity w
capable of coercive bundling than Live Nation is now. Since t
gations that Live Nation currently attempts to tie its ticket distri
promotional offerings (and, indeed, its market share in ticket distribu
Moreover, for the same reasons it makes little economic sense to b
286
See Kohl Letter, supra note 4 (“In addition, independent concert halls will likely be
under strong pressure to use Ticketmaster's ticketing services if these venues wish to get
booking from the leading acts promoted by Live Nation.”).
112
distribution with promotion. Such attempts at coerced tying would not be in the merged
bited declining
izeable.
duct and service
ndicate that they
intend to offer clients and fans a menu of bundled products, merchandise, and other
services. Without the
services will be
r’s rivals and
e Nation’s past as a
large purchaser of ticket distribution services. In other words, the theory goes, the new
venture will refuse to deal with competitors and entrants in the business of ticket
ues would not supply adequate demand to fuel a
com to challenge
the assumption
company’s best interest unless it harbored a hope that it could soon monopolize the
market for ticket distribution services, but that market instead has exhi
margins and, due to widespread Internet technologies, might be unmonopol
Again, difficulties in achieving coercive bundling does not mean that pro
bundling will not occur, and all suggestions from the merging parties i
possibility that this bundling is coercive, the presumption is that it
reflects procompetitive efficiencies.
The second theory, that Live Nation’s needs for ticket distribution
captured exclusively by the merged company, thus depriving Ticketmaste
potential entrants from that share of the market, is motivated by Liv
distribution, and the remaining ven
petitive threat to Ticketmaster. These critics conclude that for any firm
the new entity’s leadership in ticket distribution, it must enter the market at two levels–
venue ownership and ticket distribution.
287
There are several faults to this theory. First, the theory rests upon
287
Id. (“[V]enues can now [sic] be expected to solely utilize Ticketmaster’s ticketing
services. Being locked out of these concert halls is likely to make it difficult for any new
significant ticketing service to emerge after the merger.”); Pascrell Letter, supra note 4
(“The vertically integrated firm can withhold these critical inputs, and its rival will suffer.
To avoid such problems, an entrant would need to enter the industry on several levels at
once….). See generally 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 4.221
(describing how a vertical merger’s propensity to raise barriers to entry by creating a
market structure that requires two level entry can facilitate the exercise of market power).
113
that the market for ticket distribution is concentrated and that the merger enshrines
r,
be quite
er of venues that
ences in this
market appear unlikely, it is unnecessary to scrutinize whether the merger forecloses
288
recent decision to
es, a decision made
distribution,
eady lack
access to the business of distributing tickets for venues owned or managed by Live
Nation. Thus, even if the transaction somehow causes Live Nation eventually to abjure
ity about which we
tim will have no
impact whatsoever upon the opportunities for entry by possible rivals in the ticket
ansaction
d been
Ticketmaster in a position of market power. The evidence detailed in Part III, howeve
indicates that the market for ticket distribution services currently appears to
competitive. The technology for ticket distribution is becoming increasingly widespread,
with a number of new entrants in recent years as well as a growing numb
are pursuing self-distribution strategies. Because anticompetitive consequ
entry because entry is not necessary to maintain competitive conditions.
Second, the theory ignores the implications of Live Nation’s
self-distribute the tickets to events at the venues that it owns or operat
before and independent of this transaction. Given Live Nation’s self-
pursuant to a long-term contract with CTS Eventim, potential entrants alr
self-distribution, in favor of distribution by Ticketmaster (an eventual
can only speculate), such substitution of Ticketmaster for CTS Even
distribution business and thus cannot for the basis for a finding that the tr
violates Section 7.
289
This would have been the case even if the merger ha
288
See 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 4.213 (“Barriers to entry are
unlikely to affect performance if the structure of the primary market is otherwise not
conducive to monopolization or collusion.”).
289
See Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc, 386 F.3d 485, 511 (2d Cir. 2004)
(Section 7 did not forbid merger that itself had no impact on parties’ ability to exercise
market power, where any such power existed before the transaction and was not
enhanced by it). Cf. Alberta Gas Chems., 826 F.2d at 1245 (plaintiff did not suffer injury
114
proposed before Live Nation began self-distribution, when it enlisted the services of
losed under
sive ten-year
landscape of
any of which
have since challenged Ticketmaster in its traditional business. Consequently, the ticket
distribution m
etitors and entrants
rder to
f Live
Nation’s control over America’s venues. Some ticket distributors cater to niche markets
and rely on sales to small or specialized venues to recapture a portion of their fixed costs,
thereby reducing the number of large venue customers they would have to acquire to
enter the market profitably.
290
For instance, Tessitura tailors its services to the needs of
Ticketmaster. Those services were provided under exclusive contracts, so any fears of
future foreclosure cannot be more severe than what was previously forec
those contractual relationships. In fact, it was during Live Nation’s exclu
agreement with Ticketmaster when new technologies began changing the
the ticketing business and helped usher in several new market entrants, m
arket is unlikely to be altered by the merger and should be expected to
continue its recent dynamism.
Third, this theory of anticompetitive harm assumes that comp
in the ticket distribution market require access to Live Nation’s venues in o
maintain competitive profitability. This vastly overstates the significance o
a perfectly
nd subsequent conduct would have produced the very same harm);
Bayou Bottling, Inc. v. Dr. Pepper Co., 725 F.2d 300 (5th Cir. 1983). See also United
States v. Hammermill Paper Co., 429 F. Supp. 1271, 1282 (W. D. Pa. 1977) (declining to
count as “‘foreclosed” output that had already been sold to merger partner before the
transaction and thus was not available to the open market in the first place).
290
See Fruehauf, 603 F. 2d at 358 (finding that FTC overstated minimum viable scale by
ignoring fact that facilities could produce various forms of output in addition to products
in the relevant market).
cognizable under the antitrust laws as the result of a vertical merger where
lawful transaction a
115
non-profits that produce artistic performances. Additionally, experience in recent
latively
f Justice Merger
rse [that] new
m us entry into
the secondary market.” Any case against the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger based
on this “two-level entry” theory would fail for this reason alone.
294
erger with the
itigate the
ists therefore broadly view
cies, rather
operly followed
forcement agencies and courts generally taking a very lenient
view towards vertical agreements and vertical mergers.
aster merger
able without
291
years has shown that ticket distribution companies or firms that provide the software
supporting self-distribution can enter the market and remain profitable at re
modest scale.
292
Thus, this is a case in which, to quote the Department o
Guidelines, a secondary market—venues—is “sufficiently large and dive
entrants to the pri ary market [are] able to participate without simultaneo
293
Summary
We close this analysis of the vertical elements of the proposed m
following summarizing remarks and preliminary conclusions:
1. Vertical arrangements, including vertical integration, arise to m
costs of transacting in atomistic markets. Econom
vertical integration as a manifestation of organizational efficien
than as the exercise of market power. Antitrust doctrine has pr
suit, with the en
2. Economic theory predicts that the proposed Live Nation-Ticketm
is likely to produce certain efficiencies that would not be attain
complete integration.
291
Note that a firm could simultaneously enter the market for distribution
and the market
to large venues
for distribution for small venues, thereby reducing the minimum number
ssible entrant
ant consideration when determining impact of vertical transaction).
293
1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 4.211 & n.31; id. at § 4.211 (“If
there is sufficient unintegrated capacity in the secondary market [here, the venue market]
new entrants to the primary market would not have to enter both market
simultaneously.”).
294
See 1984 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, § 4.21 (requirement of two level
entry a necessary condition for a vertical merger to create harm under a “two level entry
theory”).
of large venues a firm would have to serve in order to recoup its investment.
292
Cf. Fruehauf, 603 F.2d at 353 (stating that minimum viable scale of po
is relev
116
3. The live entertainment industry appears to have exhibited a
towards vertical integration over the past decade, with many
entertainment—including those that are unlikely to enjoy any
market power—internalizing ticket distribution, live broadcas
services that create a direct interface with fans. The proposed Live Nation-
broad trend
providers of
appreciable
ts, and other
.
enshrine
et and enable
ively harm rival
dustry structure and rudimentary
economic logic, however, indicate that the vertical aspects of the merger
pact on either firm’s market power.
Ticketmaster merger appears to be part of this larger trend
4. Critics suggest that a Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger would
Ticketmaster with market power in the ticket distribution mark
Live Nation to leverage such market power to anticompetit
promoters. A careful examination of the in
would have no im
V. Conclusion
In reviewing the proposed Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger,
emerging out of a rapidly changing industry in which important technol
developments are precipitating significant organizational transformations.
technological developments—especially the spread of software platform
check on any market power that Ticketm
we observe that it is
ogical
These
s that enable
large and small venues to self-distribute tickets to their events—appear to have placed a
aster, or a merged Live Nation-Ticketmaster,
wou erged entity
tion and the
and the evident growing reliance by artists on revenue from concerts) have induced
performers, promoters, and venues to establish closer linkages with their respective fan
base. These organizational changes appear able to generate sizable efficiencies. Vertical
integration mitigates a coordination problem that hinders investment in acquiring and
disseminating information, facilitates the cooperative adaptation necessary to respond to
ld have to impose supracompetitive prices. Ultimately, whether the m
can exercise market power depends heavily on the ease of self-distribu
general availability of ticketing technologies.
These and other technological developments (including the rise of pirated music
117
unforeseen market changes and tailor responses, and enables creators of live
will foreclose
ces in
e vertical aspects
l more likely lead to efficiencies that will
benefit both consumers and the competitive process.
t the Live
t require
t the merger’s
s hard to
determine how the mechanisms underlying recent price increases would be affected by
this merger, and the efficiencies we anticipate are perhaps more likely to translate into the
ty utilization than
be reshaping the
that the
merger—and probably the general trend towards vertical integration—will negatively
impact the secondary ticket market. Certainly innovations such as paperless ticketing
will reduce opportunities for secondary sellers, and perhaps other direct linkages between
venues and fans will shut out those who seek to purchase and resell tickets. However,
any such pain inflicted on secondary sellers is the competitive process at work and should
entertainment to develop and market new content. We do not find convincing concerns
expressed by critics that the vertical integration of these companies
possibilities for efficient entry. To the contrary, and consistent with advan
institutional economics and antitrust law over the past three decades, th
of the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger wil
Our analysis does not offer balm to all of those who have expressed fears for this
merger. We should be clear that even though most evidence suggests tha
Nation-Ticketmaster merger is procompetitive and therefore should no
intervention by enforcement agencies, there is no evidence indicating tha
efficiencies will slow the steady rise in the face price of concert tickets. It i
creation of new markets, improved concert quality, and greater capaci
in lower prices.
Moreover, the merger, along with the other forces that appear to
industry, will probably be detrimental to certain parties. Some have feared
118
be compared, for example, to ills suffered by travel agents when airlines popularized and
reaped efficiencies from
igate the difficulties
t, their
produces the
ke even more
attractive offers to artists. While the vertical efficiencies are clearly good for artists and
etitors. Our
ould bring
mall venues will soon
dist they, like
Finally, our analysis offers no comfort to those who fear that the combination of
two industry leaders creates a company so large and far-reaching that smaller competitors
ic power
sed Live
mpetitors.”
295
If
the merged entity generates efficiencies such that they can produce live entertainment and
competitors, such that their competitors suffer economically, then the antitrust laws
Internet ticketing.
We also find no evidence to suggest that the merger will mit
that smaller venues currently have in securing marquee performers. In fac
difficulties might be exacerbated. If the Live Nation-Ticketmaster merger
efficiencies we anticipate, the merged entity might be in the position to ma
fans, they do place more competitive pressures on Live Nation’s comp
analysis, however, does suggest that ticketing and other technologies sh
benefits to smaller venues as well (and we predict that many s
ribute their own tickets and construct their own Internet platforms) and
other parties in the industry, will have to retool to reap new opportunities.
will be unable to effectively compete. This per se fear of size and econom
appears to be the source of most of the anxiety and ill will towards the propo
Nation-Ticketmaster merger. To these critics, antitrust has tersely and squarely said that
the nation’s antitrust laws were enacted to protect competition, not co
serve artists and consumers alike at lower costs and with higher quality than their
295
See Cargill Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, 479 U.S. 104, 115 (1986); Brunswick Corp.
v. Pueblo Bowl-o-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488 (1979).
119
120
should provide no relief. And if the proposed merger does not create efficiencies, then
resu ust laws.
297
sic industry—is
ew business
ns from
competition. To the contrary, such times are often when competition is most critical. But
laws are the law of
the land and should be applied with discipline (as we aim to do here) and without second-
guessing the deep-rooted statutory policy of maintaining competitive markets.
298
296
it necessarily creates market opportunities for these competitors. Mere size, whether
lting from internal expansion or a merger, does not offend the antitr
To be sure, the live entertainment industry—and the entire mu
undergoing significant structural change that will require developing n
models and bracing for adjustments, but times of transition are not exemptio
whatever one’s beliefs about the merits of competition, the antitrust
296
See Berkey Photo Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 276 (2d
large firm does not violate § 2 [of the Sherman Act] simply by reaping the com
rewards attributable to its efficient size, nor does an integrated business
Sherman Act whenever one of its departments benefits from association wi
possessing a mo
Cir. 1979) (“[A]
petitive
offend the
th a division
pete in
road-based
rated
considered uses of
r will likely
.S. 417 (1920)
inst relying on
political
v. Addyston
gh antitrust enforcers necessarily
exercise some discretion in allocating their resources, their priorities have generally not
reflected their policy views about the wisdom of fostering competition in a particular
sector. Those who lament recent increases in concert prices, or who wistfully recall days
of attending inexpensive and spirit-lifting concerts, see, e.g., opening statements, House
Committee Hearings, and question antitrust enforcement in the live entertainment
industry because of their own policy preferences are subversive in a way that those who
advocate rigorous enforcement of laws already on the books are not.
nopoly in its own market. So long as we allow a firm to com
several fields, we must expect it to seek the competitive advantages of its b
activity – more efficient production, greater ability to develop complementary products,
reduced transaction costs, and so forth. These are gains that accrue to any integ
firm, regardless of its market share, and they cannot by themselves be
monopoly power.”).
297
Gen. Dynamics, 415 U.S. at passim (government must prove that merge
produce anticompetitive effects); United States v. U.S. Steel Corp., 251 U
(mere size is not an offense under Section 2).
298
In 1898, then circuit judge William Howard Taft famously warned aga
“the vague and varying opinion of judges as to how much, on principles of
economy, men ought to be allowed to restrain competition.” United States
Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 283 (6th Cir. 1898). Althou